Filed by Sirius Satellite Radio Inc.
Pursuant to Rule 425 under the
Securities Act of 1933 and deemed filed
pursuant to Rule 14a-12 under the
Securities Exchange Act of 1934
Subject Company: XM Satellite Radio Holdings Inc.
Commission File No.: 0-27441
This communication contains forward-looking statements within the meaning of the Private
Securities Litigation Reform Act of 1995. Such statements include, but are not limited to,
statements about the benefits of the business combination transaction involving Sirius Satellite
Radio Inc. and XM Satellite Radio Holdings Inc., including potential synergies and cost savings and
the timing thereof, future financial and operating results, the combined companys plans,
objectives, expectations and intentions with respect to future operations, products and services;
and other statements identified by words such as anticipate, believe, plan, estimate,
expect, intend, will, should, may, or words of similar meaning. Such forward-looking
statements are based upon the current beliefs and expectations of SIRIUS and XMs management and
are inherently subject to significant business, economic and competitive uncertainties and
contingencies, many of which are difficult to predict and generally beyond the control of SIRIUS
and XM. Actual results may differ materially from the results anticipated in these forward-looking
statements.
The following factors, among others, could cause actual results to differ materially from the
anticipated results or other expectations expressed in the forward-looking statement: general
business and economic conditions; the performance of financial markets and interest rates; the
ability to obtain governmental approvals of the transaction on a timely basis; the failure of
SIRIUS and XM stockholders to approve the transaction; the failure to realize synergies and
cost-savings from the transaction or delay in realization thereof; the businesses of SIRIUS and XM
may not be combined successfully, or such combination may take longer, be more difficult,
time-consuming or costly to accomplish than expected; and operating costs and business disruption
following the merger, including adverse effects on employee retention and on our business
relationships with third parties, including manufacturers of radios, retailers, automakers and
programming providers. Additional factors that could cause SIRIUS and XMs results to differ
materially from those described in the forward-looking statements can be found in SIRIUS and XMs
Annual Reports on Form 10-K for the year ended December 31, 2006, and Quarterly Reports on Form
10-Q for the quarter ended March 31, 2007, which are filed with the Securities and Exchange
Commission (the SEC) and available at the SECs Internet site (http://www.sec.gov). The
information set forth herein speaks only as of the date hereof, and SIRIUS and XM disclaim any
intention or obligation to update any forward looking statements as a result of developments
occurring after the date of this communication.
Important Additional Information Will be Filed with the SEC
This communication is being made in respect of the proposed business combination involving
SIRIUS and XM. In connection with the proposed transaction, SIRIUS plans to file with the SEC a
Registration Statement on Form S-4 containing a Joint Proxy Statement/Prospectus and each of SIRIUS
and XM plans to file with the SEC other documents regarding the proposed transaction. The
definitive Joint Proxy Statement/Prospectus will be mailed to stockholders of SIRIUS and XM.
INVESTORS AND SECURITY HOLDERS OF SIRIUS AND XM ARE URGED TO READ THE JOINT PROXY
STATEMENT/PROSPECTUS AND OTHER DOCUMENTS FILED WITH THE SEC CAREFULLY IN THEIR ENTIRETY WHEN
THEY BECOME AVAILABLE BECAUSE THEY WILL CONTAIN IMPORTANT INFORMATION ABOUT THE PROPOSED
TRANSACTION.
Investors and security holders will be able to obtain free copies of the Registration
Statement and the Joint Proxy Statement/Prospectus (when available) and other documents filed with
the SEC by SIRIUS and XM through the web site maintained by the SEC at www.sec.gov. Free copies of
the Registration Statement and the Joint Proxy Statement/Prospectus (when available) and other
documents filed with the SEC can also be obtained by directing a request to Sirius Satellite Radio
Inc., 1221 Avenue of the Americas, 36th Floor, New York, NY 10020, Attention: Investor
Relations or by directing a request to XM Satellite Radio Holdings Inc., 1500 Eckington Place, N.E.
Washington, DC 20002, Attention: Investor Relations.
SIRIUS, XM and their respective directors and executive officers and other persons may be
deemed to be participants in the solicitation of proxies in respect of the proposed transaction.
Information regarding SIRIUS directors and executive officers is available in its Annual Report on
Form 10-K for the year ended December 31, 2006, which was filed with the SEC on March 1, 2007, and
its proxy statement for its 2007 annual meeting of stockholders, which was filed with the SEC on
April 23, 2007, and information regarding XMs directors and executive officers is available in
XMs Annual Report on Form 10-K, for the year ended December 31, 2006, which was filed with the SEC
on March 1, 2007 and its proxy statement for its 2007 annual meeting of stockholders, which was
filed with the SEC on April 17, 2007. Other information regarding the participants in the proxy
solicitation and a description of their direct and indirect interests, by security holdings or
otherwise, will be contained in the Joint Proxy Statement/Prospectus and other relevant materials
to be filed with the SEC when they become available.
***
SIRIUS
website, which is available at www.SIRIUSmerger.com and has information about SIRIUS
proposed merger, has been updated. The updates include the information being filed herewith.
TACT T E f CC NEWOlOOM wtlAT PH ARE SAVONG ... RE5O«1iCE S TACT ~s
SIRIUS~ SIRIUSmerger.com SA.TELLITE RA.DIO More choices, better prici nQ, same radios. HEAR FROM
MEL KARMAZIN. CEO OF SIRIUS RADIO. IN THE NEWS WHATS IN IT FOR YOU New Study Shows SIRIUS___XMMe
rger Enhances AOOio Compet ton You may have already heard the news that SIRIUS and XM Clic k Hereto
Rood the are talking about combining imo one company. And you may also have wondered what that will
mean for you. New Diver ,ty Ad U,led Two Can ~ay: Mock ad The answer is simple:
sOOv;;rg NAB fl ip _flOllS OrtlOtcast MORE CHOICES View All Today, fans of satellite radio must
purchase two radios and two subscriptions to get all the program offerings of both SIRIUS and XM.
If our merger is approved, the combined company will offer consumers the best of each service on
your currem radio _at a price well below the cost of the two services today. BETTER PRICING Once we
merge, you will have bener pricing choices. Subscribers who Jwant their current subscription
package will not have to pay any more after the merger. There will be new subscription packages
priced below our currem offerings. And the best of both SIRIUS and XM will be available at a lower
cost than the price of subscribing to both services separately. SA ME RADIOS We guaramee no radio
will become obsolete. Your current radio will cominue to provide you with the programming you
enjoy, whether you keep your current service or change to a new subscription plan. GET MORE DETAIL
P PRIVACY1CONTACT US I SIRI US.com ©2001 SIRIUSmerger.com |
TACT T E f CC NEWOlOOM wtlAT PH ARE SAVONG ... RE5O«1iCE. TACT ~5 SIRIUS~
SIRIUSmerger.com SA.TELLITE RA.DIO More choice s, better pricinQ. same radios. MORE ARTICLES W SJ
Notices That The NAB Has An Agenda Ted dirt April 23. 2007 W hat s the Frequency NAB ? The W all
StreBt Journal April 2 1. 2007 Terrestrial Radio Looks To Charge Subscription Fees But Still
Doesnt Compete W ith Satell te Techdirt April 19. 2007 Dinosaurs is. Satelrtes Reason Magazine.
Radley Balko April 19. 2007 More on XM-Sirius The Technology Liberation Front ~ April 11.2007 A
Merger and a Prayer (subscription requiredl Forbes April 09. 2007 Thinking Siriusl About
Satellte Radio Competition The Free State Foundation April 09. 2007 Two Can Plav. Mock ad showing
NAB flip-flops Orbitc ast April 07. 2007 NAB Shill Says He Didnt Flip-Flop Adds Sky Is Green And
Down 18 Up Techdirt April 06. 2007 Busted: Carmel Group has already defined Satelrte Radios c
ompetitors Orbitca st April 04. 2007 How Can New Satellte Radio Merger Analysis Be Independent
Wh en The NAB Paid For ~? Techdirt April 03. 2007 Busted M ke Hubbard soonsor of Alabama
anti-merger resolution ownS radio station (and morel Orbitcast -March 31 , 2007 Satelrte Sisters
The New Yorker. James Surowiecki ~ March 19. 2007 nerrestrial Radio Broadcasters Dont Compete W
ith Satellte Radio Techdirt March 01. 2007 l et XM and Sirius Merge l os Angeles Times February
27. 2007 A Monopoly Not San Francisco Chronicl e ___February 2£. 2007 They Cannot Be SIRIUS -
Satellte RadiQ The Economist February 24. 2007 SIRIUS-XM Tough l uck? Chicago Tribune February
23. 2007 SIRIUS and XM Together Makes Sense for Listeners USA Today February 23. 2007 Money Not
Outrage Fuels Anti-Merger Fight The Miami Herald February 22. 2007 Making Radio W~s W all Street
Journal February 2 1. 2007 New Diversity Ad Unveiled New Study Shows SIRIUS-XM Merger Enhances
Audio Competition Click Here to Read the Study PRIVACY I CONTACT US I SIRIUS.com tl2001
SIRIUSmerger.c om |
TACT T E f CC NEWOlOOM wtlAT PH ARE SAVONG ... RE5O«1iCE. TACT ~5 SIRIUS~
SIRIUSmerger.com SA.TELLITE RA.DIO More choice s, better pricinQ. same radios. WHAT PEOPLE ARE
SAYING Radio station owners have long studied the issue of radio rivalry. and have for ~r a
dade asserted that satellite radio offers a dangerous comre titrve threat. In advocating that
regulators deny the profO sed merger. broadc asters document that its likely efft will be to
prc,,;d e satellite radio listeners more. not less. seMc e for their subscription dolla Thomas
Hazlett Professor of Law & Ec onomics George Mason University For the most part. the mainstream
media c ompanies offer very limited music and entertainment programming targeted to the Hispanic c
ommunity. Satellite radio. by contrast. does prc,,;d e sought after programming such as CNN en
Espano!. ESPN DefOrtes. and Mexico Canta W e believe that satellite radio prc,,;d es expanding and
,,;brant platforms for news and entertainment for Hispanic Americ ans Lillian Rodriguez-lopez
President Hispanic FiNerati on The farms and rural communities we represent have been well served
by satellite radio. Approva l of the merger between Sirius and XM will ensure that our rural c
ommunities continue to receive important informational seMce ,,;a satellite radio and will prc,,;de
our members and rural neighbors with more programming choic es at improved pric es Pam Potthoff
National President W omen Involved in Farm Economics Especially imfO rtant to our membership is
the c ommitment the parties have made to issue refunds to satellite radio subscribers who choose to
block adult-themed programming .. W ith all of the indent and ,,;olent programming bombarding Am
eric an families today. we applaud the efforts of Sirius and XM to emfOwer c onsumers who want to
oid such c ontent This is cl early a step in the right direction Gar; Bauer President
American Values Consolidation of the terrestrial radio industry ~r the last dade has left much
of rural Americ a behind in rent years. as locally owned stations are replaced by
megaorfOrate conglomerates which produce homogenized c ontent and so alled local news and
weather delrvered from hundreds of miles away The emergence of satellite radio has offered
listeners in rural areas a robust alternative with hundreds of specialized channels that c ater to
the programming needs of rural Am eric a. Ni~ Ritchie ExecutIVe P tor league of Rural Voters
F or far too long. the l atino marl et has fallen ,,;ctim to traditional radio comp anies
that target vefY narrow and highly profitable audiences Under this frameworl, Hispanic s lose
out on news. sfOrts. music and diverse cultural programming that is widely aailable on alternative
sourc es such as satellite. HP and internet radio. The satellite radio industry. by contrast. has
been a launching pad for Hispanic programmers and an increasingly fOpu lar seMc e for vast numbers
of Latino consumers and othe listeners who enjoy the richness of Hispanic culture arts and
"~ Robert G de Posada President The Latino Coal tion Comretitors that are threatened by the
prospect of a thrMng satellite radio c ompany have launchiN a self-interested c ampaign aimed at
killing the merge. by asserting that an XM-Sirius alliance would constitute a monofOly.
Despite their cl aims. the merger of XM and Sirius would be beneficial to consumers and deserves
SUpfOrt. John Berthoud President National Taxpayers Union Satellite radio is critic al to the
programming neiN s of Afric an Americ ans The medium offers dozens of channels that are targeted to
the programming needs of Afric an Am eric an entrepreneurs. entertainers. and consumers
In fact.
Internet radio. music download seMce s. and satellite radio have all played critic al roles in
democratizing the music and audio industry allowing c onsumers acc ess to a ,,;rtual on-J emand
world Har Alford President National Black Chamber of Commerce Satellite radio is a critical
miN ium for Hispanic Am eric ans. making aailable a wide range of listening choic es that are not
generally ailable on traditional broadc ast radio For example. ESPN DefOrtes. CNN Espafiol, and
several Latin music channels Brent W ilkes EXK ut;W PirK tor League of United Latin American
Citizens The botto m line is that with expanded choic es and bett er prices, satellite radio will
be an even more attractive option for c onsumers, and this ultimately benefits our Chamber members
and the two-million Latinoowned businesses in the U.S . There is no doubt that the XM-Sirius
merger will be a win-win for Hispanic businesses and the c ommunity and we strongly urge its
approva l Alfred P. Placeres Esc President New York State FiNerati on of Hispanic Chambers of
Commerce lndeiN , if the National Association of Broadc asters and its terrestrial broadc aster
allies are able to rersuade the Department of Justic e and the FCC to prevent the SiriusiXM merger
on the basis that satellite radio c onstitutes a discrete product market, well then, maybe rt1
become a believer in the Easter Bunny too. Randy May, Thinking Siriusly About Satellite Radio
Comretition April 9, 2007 ., think all of us would agree. though, that these two. the merger of
these two is not going to create a monofOly in any sense because there is a lot of comre tition
out there with the broadcast and the Internet and wireless and iPod, as others have mentioned -
Rep Cliff Stearns (FL), 3/7 House Committ ee on Energy and Commerces pan~ on The Future of Radio
Stop throwing around the word ·monofOly. The comretition they have is WITh radio stations
charging zero dollars for the same or a similar product. Rep Anthony W einer (NY), 2128 House
Judiciary Committee antitrust task forc e PRIVACY 1CONTACT US 1 SIRIUS.com V2001
SIRIUSme,ge,.com |
TACT T E f CC NEWOlOOM wtlAT PH ARE SAVONG ... RE5O«1iCE. TACT ~5
SIRIUS~ SIRIUSmerger.com SA.TELLITE RA.DIO More choices, better pricinQ. same radios. MERGER
RESOURCES 230 U Competition Mill. 12S .~- in Audio 116 SOl; .RAD Entertainment 00 7S 72
""'.. ""' so 23.5 25 e 14 - , ... .- ___""... 0 1tAM,IF.
..,- ..., ... .., . ... Sate llite Radio is a Small Part of a Hig hly Competitive
and Ever-Expa nding Market f or Aud io Entertain ment GET MORE The audio entertainment market today
is ;brant. com,.etitiw. and innatiw. INF ORMATlON and every indic ation is that it will te
even more so in the future W e telieve that the combination of SIRIUS and XM will te good
for consumers as it will intensify this com,.etition. expand the choices for consumers, and reduc e
· SIRIUSlXM re releases prices SIRIUSlXM pnnt dvertising The
market for audio entertainment in the United States is robustly com,.etitive and rapidly ,, ng
SIRIUS and XM must com,.ete directly and Audio Entertainment intensely with a host of
other audio prOid ers for consumer att ention Markel fact shets Congressional
testimony SIRIUS/XM press re leases Federal Communications Commission ~li9s
SIRIUS and XM Announce Merger Mer9"' AJ1a1ysis SIRIUS Radio Guarantee Press Release
· SIRIUS Radio Guarantee SIRIUS and XM Unveil [liyersity M New Study Shows SIRIUS-XM Merger
Enhance s Audio Comootition SIRIUS/XM print advertis in g Even Bett er TMether M Wha!s In
It for Consumersr Ad listen to the Numters M =Perse Merger Supoort M Aud io Entertain
ment Market f act sheets Audio Competition Fact SheB1 NABs Campaign Against Satell te Radio
NABs Gpoosition to Competition NAB W hat They Said Then IS Wh at They are Saying Now Cong
ressio nal t est imo ny ill House Judiciary Committ ees Antitrust Task Force February 28
2007 House Energy and Commerce Committ ees SuPro mmittee on Telecommunications anll the Internet
- - March 7 2007 Senate Judiciary Committees SuPromm itt ee on Ant itrust Comootition Policy and
Consumer Rights March 20 2007 Senate Committee on Commerce Science and Transportation April
17 Federal Commu nicatio ns Commissio n f ilings FCC Applicat ion for Merger SIRIUS SEC Form
8-K [3113/200n FCC Public Comment Notice Merg er Analysis The Economics ofthe Satellte Raljio
Merger PRIVACY I CONTACT US I SIRIUS.com (Cl2001 SIRIUSme ,ge,.com |
In addition, the Merger Resources page of the website also contains a link to the following
FCC public notice included on the website:
|
|
|
Federal Communications Commission
445 12thSt., S.W.
Washington, D.C. 20554
|
|
News Media Information 202 / 418-0500
Internet: http://www.fcc.gov
TTY: 1-888-835-5322 |
DA 07-2417
Released: June 8, 2007
MEDIA BUREAU ACTION
SIRIUS SATELLITE RADIO INC. AND XM SATELLITE RADIO HOLDINGS INC. SEEK
APPROVAL TO TRANSFER CONTROL OF FCC AUTHORIZATIONS AND LICENSES
MB Docket No. 07-57
PLEADING CYCLE ESTABLISHED
Comments/Petitions Due: July 9, 2007
Responses/Oppositions Due: July 24, 2007
On March 20, 2007, Sirius Satellite Radio Inc. (Sirius) and XM Satellite Radio Holdings Inc.
(XM) (collectively, the Applicants) submitted applications seeking consent to transfer control
of Commission licenses and authorizations held by Sirius, XM, and their subsidiaries pursuant to
Section 310(d) of the Communications Act of 1934, as amended.1 Under the proposed
transaction and pursuant to an Agreement and Plan of Merger dated February 19, 2007, a wholly owned
subsidiary of Sirius, Vernon Merger Corporation, will be merged with and into XM, with XM being the
surviving entity of this subsidiary merger.2 The surviving entity will be controlled by
a new Board of Directors, selected by both Sirius and XM, and its equity ownership will be
represented equally by former shareholders of XM and Sirius prior to the merger.
GENERAL INFORMATION
The Consolidated Application for approval of the transfer of control of the licenses and
authorizations referenced herein, upon initial review, has been accepted for filing. The
Commission reserves the right to return any application if, upon further examination, it is
determined to be defective and not in conformance with the Commissions rules, regulations, or
policies.
|
|
|
1 |
|
See 47 U.S.C. § 310(d); Applications of XM Satellite Radio Holdings Inc.,
Transferor, and Sirius Satellite Radio Inc., Transferee, For Consent to Transfer Control, MB Docket
No. 07-57 (filed March 20, 2007) (collectively, the Consolidated Application). On March 29,
2007, the Commission released a public notice designating this proceeding as permit but disclose
for purposes of the Commissions ex parte rules. See XM Satellite Radio Holdings, Inc. and Sirius
Satellite Radio, Inc. Seek Approval To Transfer Control Of Licensee Entities Holding FCC Licenses
and Other Authorizations, DA 07-1435, MB Docket No. 07-57 (rel. Mar. 29, 2007). |
|
2 |
|
A complete list of the licenses and authorizations held by Sirius and XM that are
subject to the Consolidated Application is set forth in the Attachment. |
Interested parties must file petitions to deny, comments, or informal comments no later
than July 9, 2007. Persons that do not file petitions to deny may not seek reconsideration of the
Commissions decision regarding the transfer of the licenses at issue nor appeal a final
decision to the courts but may otherwise participate in the proceeding. Responses or oppositions
to such submissions must be filed no later than July 24, 2007. All filings concerning matters
referenced in this Public Notice should refer to MB Docket No. 07-57, as well as the specific file
numbers of the individual applications or other matters to which the filings pertain (unless a
filing pertains to all applications).
Under the Commissions current procedures for the submission
of filings and other documents, submissions in this matter may be filed electronically (i.e.,
through ECFS) or by hand delivery to the
Commissions Massachusetts Avenue location noted below.
|
|
|
Electronic Filers: Comments
may be filed electronically using the
Internet by accessing the ECFS:
http://www.fcc.gov/cgb/ecfs/. In completing
the transmittal screen, filers should include
their full name, U.S. Postal Service mailing
address, and MB Docket No. 07-57. Parties
may also submit an electronic comment by
Internet e-mail. To get filing instructions,
filers should send an e-mail to ecfs@fcc.gov,
and include the following words in the body
of the message, get form. A sample form
and directions will be sent in response. |
|
|
|
|
Paper Filers: Parties who choose to
file by paper must file an original and four
copies of each filing. |
|
|
|
|
Filings can be sent by hand or messenger
delivery, by commercial overnight courier, or
by first-class or overnight U.S. Postal
Service mail (although we continue to
experience delays in receiving U.S. Postal
Service mail). All filings must be addressed
to the Commissions Secretary, Office of the
Secretary, Federal Communications Commission. |
|
|
|
The Commissions contractor
will receive hand-delivered or
messenger-delivered paper filings for the
Commissions Secretary at 236 Massachusetts
Avenue, NE, Suite 110, Washington, DC 20002.
The filing hours at this location are 8:00
a.m. to 7:00 p.m. All hand deliveries must
be held together with rubber bands or
fasteners. Any envelopes must be disposed of
before entering the building. |
|
|
|
|
Commercial overnight mail
(other than U.S. Postal Service Express Mail
and Priority Mail) must be sent to 9300 East
Hampton Drive, Capitol Heights, MD 20743. |
|
|
|
|
U.S. Postal Service
first-class, Express, and Priority mail must
be addressed to 445 12th Street,
SW, Washington, DC 20554. |
|
|
|
|
People with Disabilities: To
request materials in accessible formats for
people with disabilities (braille, large
print, electronic files, audio format), send
an e-mail to fcc504@fcc.gov or call the
Consumer & Governmental Affairs Bureau at
202-418-0530 (voice), 202-418-0432 (tty). |
In addition, one copy of each submission must be sent to each of the following:
1. The Commissions duplicating contractor, Best Copy and Printing, Inc., Portals II, 445
12thStreet, S.W., Room CY-B402, Washington, DC 20554, telephone 1-800-378-3160, or via
e-mail at www.bcpiweb.com;
2
2. Rosemary C. Harold, Media Bureau, Room 3-C486; e-mail Rosemary.Harold@fcc.gov;3
3. Tracy Waldon, Media Bureau, Room 3-C488; e-mail Tracy.Waldon@fcc.gov;
4. Royce Sherlock, Media Bureau, Room 2-C360; e-mail Royce.Sherlock@fcc.gov;
5. Jim Bird, Office of General Counsel, Room 8-C824; e-mail Jim.Bird@fcc.gov;
6. Gardner Foster, International Bureau, Room 6-C477; e-mail Gardner.Foster@fcc.gov;
7. Marilyn Simon, International Bureau, Room 6-A633; e-mail Marilyn.Simon@fcc.gov;
8. Marcia Glauberman, Media Bureau, Room 2-C264; e-mail Marcia.Glauberman@fcc.gov;
9. Amy Brett, Media Bureau, Room 2-C134; e-mail Amy.Brett@fcc.gov;
10. Erin McGrath, Wireless Bureau, Room 6338 (Portals I); e-mail Erin.McGrath@fcc.gov.
Copies of the Consolidated Application and any subsequently filed documents in this matter may
be obtained from Best Copy and Printing, Inc., Portals II, 445 12th Street, SW, Room
CY-B402, Washington, D.C. 20554, telephone 1-800-378-3160, or via-e-mail www.bcpiweb.com. The
Consolidated Application and any associated documents are also available for public inspection and
copying during normal reference room hours at the following Commission office: FCC Reference
Information Center, 445 12th Street, S.W., Room CY-A257, Washington, D.C. 20554. These
materials are also available electronically through the Commissions ECFS, which may be accessed on
the Commissions Internet website at http://www.fcc.gov. Additional information regarding the
transaction will be available on the FCCs Office of General Counsels website,
http://www.fcc.gov/ogc, which will contain a fully indexed, unofficial listing and electronic
copies of all materials in this Docket.
For further information, contact Rosemary C. Harold, (202)
418-2533, Royce Sherlock, (202) 418-7030, or Marcia Glauberman, (202) 418-7046, of the Media
Bureau. Press inquiries should be directed to Mary Diamond, (202) 418-2388. TTY: (202) 418-7172 or
(888) 835-5322.
[FCC]
|
|
|
3 |
|
The street address for all Commission staff is 445 12th Street, S.W., Washington, D.C. 20554. |
3
ATTACHMENT
The Consolidated Application filed by XM and Sirius includes applications pertaining to the
Commission authorizations and licenses listed below. They are separated below by the type of
authorization or license, and, within each category, listed by licensee/registrant name,
application file number, call sign, and/or other service-specific information, as appropriate.
Interested parties should refer to the Consolidated Application for a more detailed listing of the
authorizations or licenses. Each of the Applicants subsidiaries or affiliates may hold multiple
authorizations or licenses of a particular type. Parties should be aware that additional
applications may have to be filed to identify any additional authorizations involved in this
transaction.
Part 25 Satellite Communications
|
|
|
|
|
File No. |
|
Licensee/Registrant |
|
Call Sign(s) |
Satellite Space Stations |
|
|
|
|
SAT-T/C-20070320-00054
|
|
XM Radio, Inc.
|
|
S2118 |
|
|
|
|
S2119 |
|
|
|
|
S2616 |
|
|
|
|
S26174 |
|
|
|
|
|
SAT-T/C-20070320-00053
|
|
Satellite CD Radio, Inc.
|
|
S21055 |
|
|
|
|
|
Satellite Earth Stations |
|
|
|
|
SES-T/C-20070320-00380
|
|
XM Radio, Inc.
|
|
E000158 |
|
|
|
|
E000724 |
|
|
|
|
E040204 |
|
|
|
|
|
SES-T/C-20070320-00379
|
|
Sirius Satellite Radio, Inc.
|
|
E040363 |
|
|
|
|
E060276 |
|
|
|
|
E060277 |
|
|
|
|
E990291 |
|
|
|
4 |
|
The following applications for special temporary authority (either pending or in
effect) to operate terrestrial repeaters are associated with the XM Radio Inc. space stations:
SAT-STA-20070222-00037; SAT-STA-20070222-00036; SAT-STA-20070205-00026; SAT-STA-20061211-00147;
SAT-STA-20061114-00138; SAT-STA-20061013-00120; SAT-STA-20061013-00119; SAT-STA-20061002-00114;
SAT-STA-20050712-00145; SAT-STA-20050601-00113; SAT-STA-20050307-00056; SAT-STA-20031219-00373;
SAT-STA-20031112-00371; SAT-STA-20030409-00076; SAT-STA-20030325-00056; SAT-STA-20020815-00153;
SAT-STA-20020311-00049; SAT-STA-20010712-00063; and SAT-STA-20070330-00059. |
|
5 |
|
The following applications for special temporary authority (either pending or in
effect) to operate terrestrial repeaters are associated with the Satellite CD Radio, Inc. space
stations: SAT-STA-20070327-00057; SAT-STA-20061208-00146; SAT-STA-20061207-00145;
SAT-STA-20061107-00135; SAT-STA-20061107-00133; SAT-STA-20061107-00132; SAT-STA-20061107-00131;
SAT-STA-20061013-00122; SAT-STA-20061013-00121; SAT-STA-20060623-00067; SAT-STA-20050601-00114;
SAT-STA-20050301-00053; SAT-STA-20040623-00122; SAT-STA-20040623-00119; SAT-STA-20031106-00370;
SAT-STA-20030411-00075; SAT-STA-20020222-00028; SAT-STA-20031219-00369; SAT-STA-20020312-00048;
SAT-STA-20020827-00162; SAT-STA-20020827-00248; SAT-STA-20030827-00299; SAT-STA-20020312-00029; and
SAT-STA-20010724-00064. |
4
Part 90- Wireless License
|
|
|
|
|
File No. |
|
Licensee |
|
Call Sign |
0002948781
|
|
Sirius Satellite Radio Inc.
|
|
WPTX369 |
Part 5- Experimental License
|
|
|
|
|
File No. |
|
Licensee |
|
Call Sign |
004-EX-TC-2007
|
|
XM Radio, Inc.
|
|
WB2XCA XD |
5
In
addition, the More Articles, and What People Are
Saying and Merger Resources pages of the website also contain a link to the following
merger analysis included on the website:
June 14, 2007
VIA HAND DELIVERY
Marlene H. Dortch
Secretary
Federal Communications Commission
445 12th Street, SW
Washington, D.C. 20554
|
|
|
Re: |
|
Consolidated Application for Authority to Transfer Control of XM Radio Inc.
and Sirius Satellite Radio Inc., MB Docket No. 07-57 |
Dear Ms. Dortch:
I have been retained by Sirius and XM to analyze the above-referenced merger. Attached, for
consideration by the Commission, please find the study I have prepared, The Economics of the
Satellite Radio Merger. This paper explains that approval of this transaction will create a
superior satellite radio company that, through efficiencies gained in operations and finance, will
offer an enhanced package of valuable services to consumers. This paper further demonstrates the
erroneous nature of arguments advocated by merger opponents, who argue that satellite radio is a
separate and distinct market and that combining XM and Sirius will create a merger to monopoly.
I ask that you include this paper in the record of the above-referenced proceeding.
Sincerely,
Thomas Hazlett
Professor of Law & Economics, George Mason University
Principal, Arlington Economics
|
|
|
cc: |
|
The Honorable Kevin Martin
The Honorable Michael Copps
The Honorable Jonathan Adelstein
The Honorable Deborah Taylor Tate
The Honorable Robert McDowell
Daniel Gonzalez
Catherine Bohigian
|
1655 North Fort Myer Drive * Suite 700 * Arlington, Virginia 22209 * (703) 351-5248
www.ArlingtonEconomics.com
|
|
|
Letter to Federal Communications Commission
|
|
page 2 |
|
|
|
|
|
Monica Desai
Helen Domenici
Michelle Carey
Erika Olsen
Scott Deutchman
Bruce Gottlieb
Barry Ohlson
Rudy Brioché
Aaron Goldberger
Angela E. Giancarlo
Cristina Chou Pauzé
|
THE ECONOMICS OF THE
SATELLITE RADIO MERGER
Thomas W. Hazlett1
Professor of Law & Economics,
George Mason University
June 14, 2007
|
|
|
1 |
|
The author previously served as Chief Economist of the Federal Communications
Commission and is a principal in Arlington Economics. This study was commissioned by XM and Sirius.
The views expressed are solely those of the author. |
TABLE OF CONTENTS
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
EXECUTIVE SUMMARY |
|
|
3 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
I. |
|
INTRODUCTION |
|
|
6 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
II. |
|
RIVALRY AND ANTITRUST |
|
|
9 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
III. |
|
CONSUMER IMPACT |
|
|
12 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
A. |
|
Financially Strengthening Competitive Entrants into Radio |
|
|
13 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
B. |
|
Direct Gains for Consumers |
|
|
17 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
IV. |
|
SATELLITE RADIO COMPETITION |
|
|
22 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
A. |
|
Historic Rivalry Between Satellite and Terrestrial Radio |
|
|
22 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
B. |
|
The Cable and Broadcast TV Analogy |
|
|
25 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
C. |
|
Competition in Audio Services |
|
|
27 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
V. |
|
SIDAKS MERGER ANALYSIS |
|
|
29 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
A. |
|
The Critical Own-Price Elasticity Model |
|
|
31 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
B. |
|
An Asserted Duopoly Market with Negative Profits |
|
|
32 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
C. |
|
Defining Markets Narrowly: XM Doesnt Compete with Sirius |
|
|
33 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
D. |
|
Market Shares by the Channel Capacity Metric |
|
|
34 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
E. |
|
A Static Model |
|
|
38 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
VI. |
|
CONCLUSION |
|
|
44 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
APPENDIX 1 |
|
|
46 |
|
2
|
|
|
|
|
|
Thomas W. Hazlett
|
|
The Economics of the Satellite Radio Merger |
EXECUTIVE SUMMARY
The proposed XM-Sirius merger will increase competition among providers of audio
entertainment. The February 2007 announcement that XM Satellite Radio and Sirius Satellite Radio
plan to merge has generated heated opposition from terrestrial broadcasters. These interests
emphatically claim that they oppose the merger because it will lead to a monopoly that will harm
consumers. This fierce opposition is powerful evidence in itself that AM/FM radio free radio
competes with satellite radio, and reveals the true concern of terrestrial stations: that the
merger will create a stronger rival better able to meet the needs of consumers. If terrestrial
broadcasters genuinely believed that the merger would increase prices and decrease satellite
subscriber growth, they would favor the transaction, which would translate into larger audiences
and ad revenues for them. Since even before satellite radio systems were launched, broadcasters
have consistently argued that the media constitutes a competitive threat, and have repeatedly
attempted to restrain this new service, via regulation, to protect their competitive turf.
Numerous independent investment analysts have concluded that the proposed merger will yield
substantial efficiencies. The merger is expected to lift the financial prospects of satellite
radio, lower capital financing costs, and foster economies of scale. Consensus estimates identify
cost synergies of between $3 billion and $7 billion in net present value equal (at the
mid-point) to about half the aggregate enterprise value of XM and Sirius combined. These savings
will permit more aggressive investment in satellite systems and products and prompt competitive
responses from terrestrial broadcasters and other competitors. Indeed, terrestrial broadcasters
have already launched HD digital radio as a response to satellite radio.
Through these efficiencies, XM and Sirius will be able to compete more effectively for market share
and will lure more subscribers from free radio. That is precisely what terrestrial radio
broadcasters fear. They recognize that satellite radio is a substitute for their product, and that
a merger would enhance the attractiveness of satellite radio as a competitive alternative. While
the terrestrial radio broadcasters dress their opposition in the rubric of antitrust law, their
strategy to prevent this efficient market restructuring by obtaining regulatory intervention is an
attempt to use antitrust law to subvert competition.
Consumers will benefit from the proposed merger in two ways. First, by combining two small players
in the audio entertainment market, the transaction will bring economic vitality to satellite
broadcasters and strengthen the financial position of upstart competitors in radio broadcasting.
This, in turn, will sustain a wide range of valuable consumer options and spawn new services and
products. When costs of capital for satellite radio (now extraordinarily high) are reduced, market
rivalry will intensify, spurring competitors to innovate and make product upgrades that are
otherwise uneconomical. Second, consumers benefit from lower-cost products and services, as well as
wider program choice. By combining operations, satellite operators seek to create greater scale
economies in radio receivers, and to supply a wider array of popular
3
|
|
|
|
|
|
Thomas W. Hazlett
|
|
The Economics of the Satellite Radio Merger |
programming to subscribers. Instead of making choices between channels carried exclusively by one
satellite carrier or the other and then shouldering risks associated with changes in program
line-ups or their own preferences down the road, customers will be able to confidently access their
favorite satellite radio content.
There is intense inter-modal competition among providers of audio entertainment. Consumers have a wide range of choices, including advertising-supported terrestrial broadcasting,
subscription satellite radio, MP3 devices, and other emerging digital media. Further, the fact that
there are widely disparate pricing models among these platforms demonstrates that the competitive
frontier is largely defined in terms of quality and convenience of service, rather than price. In
markets presenting these competitive dynamics, it is simply a mistake to employ static models or to
focus only on nominal prices to define or evaluate the market. The more important question here is
whether a change in performance attributes would cause consumers to substitute one product or
service for another. And, taking the dynamic nature of the market into account, it is clear that
satellite radio broadcasters are not dominant players but compete with a host of other products and
services including terrestrial radio.
It is instructive that the investment community consensus is that the XM-Sirius merger will lead to
enormous synergies. Analysts see the merger not as an attempt to procure gains by increasing
consumer prices, but rather as an attempt by satellite radio providers to drive costs down and to
offer a more competitive product. The perceived strategy is to hold down prices while expanding
product quality. Independent projections show an increase in post-merger subscriber growth due to
more programming choices a pro-consumer outcome. A merger that reduces effective prices to
subscribers and delivers billions of dollars worth of cost saving efficiencies is in the public
interest under either a consumer welfare or a total welfare standard.
By any measure, satellite radio is dwarfed by terrestrial radio. The most common market share
metric is revenue. On that scale, terrestrial broadcasters accounted for over $21 billion in sales
in 2006, as compared to just $1.6 billion for satellite less than 7% of overall radio revenues.
This helps to explain why investors place an enterprise value of about $82 billion on terrestrial
stations, as against about $9 billion for satellite radio.
A flurry of new consumer electronics products and services offer customers increasingly broad audio
entertainment choices. When iPods and other digital audio media are considered in addition to
terrestrial broadcasting, satellites revenue share falls to 4%. Internet radio is heard weekly by
over 50 million Americans, far more than tune into satellite radio. And over 230 million cell phone
subscribers now carry mobile handsets, devices embedding the capacity to download MP3 files, access
radio broadcasts via broadband links, or tune to AM or FM stations directly.
Static models of the sort used by merger opponents to evaluate this proposed combination fail to
reflect market dynamics, ignoring innovation, performance-based competition, and the key role of
investment. In one important analysis funded by the National Association of Broadcasters, an
economic model is used to assert that satellite radio constitutes its
4
|
|
|
|
|
|
Thomas W. Hazlett
|
|
The Economics of the Satellite Radio Merger |
own market, separate and distinct from terrestrial radio. In fact, the model and the facts on which
the analysis is based actually identify XM and Sirius as operating in separate markets, thus
obviating competitive concerns over an XM-Sirius merger. Further, it is noteworthy that the
duopoly or monopoly satellite radio market alleged to exist exhibits a market value that is
less than the present value of funds invested. Without competitive profits, let alone monopoly
profits, such market boundaries are illusory.
Social gains result from efficiency-creating financial transactions. The consensus forecast is
that pronounced synergies would attend an XM-Sirius merger, placing satellite radio in a stronger
and more competitive position. The anticipated gains represent an enormous increase in economic
welfare, with gains distributed to both consumers and producers. Consumers are likely to see
improved quality and service without a corresponding increase in price because of the merger.
Estimates suggest that these benefits will lead to considerable growth in the number of subscribers
to satellite radio at existing prices. For these reasons, Wall Street analysts have argued in
favor of this transaction since long before the parties negotiated a merger agreement. And they
explain why incumbent broadcasters oppose it.
5
|
|
|
|
|
|
Thomas W. Hazlett
|
|
The Economics of the Satellite Radio Merger |
I. INTRODUCTION
One can hear the winds of change.
While the implications are rarely noticed, the audio services that Americans use in their
everyday lives are in tumult. In recent years society has adopted a stunning array of new consumer
electronics, with a curiously high proportion altering what we hear and how we hear it. Of the top
ten consumer innovations over the past quarter-century, USA Today lists five audio products, among
them cellphones, Blackberries, DVDs and iPods.2 These devices have, in turn, almost
entirely displaced what was so new and innovative to previous generations, including eight-track
tapes, audio cassettes, and transistor radios.3
Into this sea of change dove satellite radio operators XM and Sirius. Spending years to
convince regulators to allocate spectrum enabling an exciting new audio content delivery platform,
the idea eventually took hold. In 1997, two licenses were auctioned by the federal
government4; satellites were launched in 1999 and 2000; consumers began receiving
satellite radio service in 2001. The new operators supplied rich, diverse program menus each
featuring over 100 channels of news, sports, entertainment, and information.
Consumer response has been enthusiastic. Some 14 million subscribers pay $12.95 a month for
satellite radio5, revealing a rapid adoption rate. But the financial burdens are equally
impressive. Together the two firms have expended about $10 billion more than they have garnered in
revenues; the market value of the firms reflects expectations that investors will not fully recoup
losses. Both XM and Sirius underwent debt restructuring in early 2003. As was reported:
Digital competitors Sirius and XM Satellite Radio launched monthly subscription
alternatives to AM and FM radio after spending billions on risky satellite systems to
attract subscribers by providing national coverage, higher quality audio and
advertising-free programming. But
|
|
|
2 |
|
The list: (1) cellular phones; (2) laptop computers; (3) Blackberries; (4) debit
cards; (5) caller I.D.; (6) DVDs; (7) lithium rechargeable batteries; (8) iPods; (9) pay at the
pump; (10) lettuce in a bag. 25 Years of Eureka Moments, USA Today (May 21,
2007); http://www.switched.com/2007/05/21/top-25-tech-inventions-of-the-last-25-years/4. |
|
3 |
|
USA Today includes the first and last of these in its list of 25
social institutions that have been lost over the past quarter century. The Long Goodbye, USA
Today (June 4, 2007); file:///C:/Documents%20and%20Settings/Compaq_Administrator/My%20Documents/top25disappear.USA.Today.6.4.07.htm. |
|
4 |
|
International Bureau Grants Satellite Digital Radio Authorization to Satellite CD
Radio, Inc., Federal Communications Commission News Release, (Oct. 10, 1997);
http://www.fcc.gov/Bureaus/International/News_Releases/1997/nrin7036.html. |
|
5 |
|
Richard Siklos and Andrew Ross Sorkin, Merger Would End Satellite Radios Rivalry, N.Y. Times (Feb. 20, 2007);
http://www.nytimes.com/2007/02/20/business/media/20radio.html?ex=1329714000&en=e5462230fee9f582&ei=5124&partner=permalink&exprod=permalink. |
6
|
|
|
|
|
|
Thomas W. Hazlett
|
|
The Economics of the Satellite Radio Merger |
both companies debt levels have left serious doubts about their ability to survive
until they can sign up enough subscribers to offset their costs.6
The firms have survived. They have reduced their debt loads. But they are yet to prosper.
Investment analysts have long seen both companies best chance to become financially formidable,
more potent inter-modal competitors, as merger. Consensus estimates place the cost-saving
synergies as extremely high, from $3 billion to $7 billion in net present value.7 Merger
is not seen to promote price increases, but to increase subscriber growth via higher product
quality given broader offerings of the most popular content. Such sweeping efficiencies would
clearly fortify their efforts to rival incumbent stations and to claw their way to profitability in
the increasingly competitive marketplace for audio consumer electronics.
Since the announcement on February 19, 2007 that XM and Sirius planned to combine operations
in a merger of equals, there has been much discussion of the effect this transaction will have on
competition. Merger opponents argue that satellite radio is a separate and distinct market, and
combining the two operators will create merger to monopoly. This begs the questions: why are
terrestrial broadcasters (a) responding to satellite rivalry by investing in HD radio8
and reducing commercial time9; (b) filing regulatory pleadings, arguing repeatedly, over
fifteen years, that satellite is a competitive
|
|
|
6 |
|
Ben Charny, Funds Orbit Sirius Away from Bankruptcy, CNET News.com (March 5, 2003);
http://news.com.com/Funds+orbit+Sirius+away+from+bankruptcy/2100-1035_3-991269.html?tag=news.1. |
|
7 |
|
XM, SIRIUS and XM to Combine in $13 Billion Merger of Equals, News Release (Feb. 19,
2007) [XM 2007]; http://xmradio.mediaroom.com/index.php? s=press_releases&item=1423. |
|
8 |
|
Digital radio broadcasting is critically important for terrestrial stations in view
of the launch of two satellite distributed digital audio radio services in 2001. Hence, the dawning
of terrestrial digital radio is driven more by marketplace and competitive concerns as opposed to
the digital television conversion timeline mandated by the FCC. Donald R. Lockett, The Road to
Digital Radio in the United States (Washington, D.C.: National Association of Broadcasters;
2004), p. xvii. The book was published as an NAB Executive Technology Briefing. |
|
9 |
|
Facing increasing competition from satellite radio and iPods, Clear Channel
Communications is trying something radically different at a commercial radio station in Texas:
getting rid of the commercials. The station uses sponsors each hour, allowing announcers to
promote the sponsors product conversationally. The product-themed chitchat will account for
about two minutes peppered throughout the hour, in contrast to the 12 minutes to 16 minutes of
commercials that most stations broadcast each hour. Andrew Adam Newman, In Dallas, Commercial
Radio Without Commercials, N.Y. Times (April 23, 2007), [Newman 2007]; http://www.nytimes.com/2007/04/23/business/media/23radio.html?ex=1334980800&en=670c621e96d488ef&ei=5088&partner=rssnyt&emc=rss. |
7
|
|
|
|
|
|
Thomas W. Hazlett
|
|
The Economics of the Satellite Radio Merger |
threat endangering terrestrial radios profitability;10 and (c) opposing the satellite
merger, urging regulators to block it?11
The campaign against XM-Sirius presents a fall-back market definition, one that includes radio
stations in the relevant market. But the market share measures used are based on the number of
channels offered listeners.12 If Clear Channel owns five stations in a market, and other
terrestrial broadcasters own 25, the Clear Channel market share = 1.5%, the XM (170 channel) market
share = 51%, and Sirius (133 channels) = 40%.
The methodology purports to show that a satellite radio merger would be highly problematic
according to the Department of Justice/Federal Trade Commission Merger Guidelines. The logic,
however, clashes frontally with market realities. The market share analysis conducted posits that
satellite radio is the overwhelmingly dominant radio service. This would surprise investors, who
value terrestrial radio broadcasting properties at more than eight times the level of satellite
operators. Indeed, they value one broadcaster, Clear Channel, at more than twice the value of XM
and Sirius combined. Based on revenues, the most common metric for market share analysis, satellite
accounts for under 7% of radio broadcasting sales. If iPods and other digital audio media are
included, satellites revenue share falls to 4%.13
Consumers easily substitute for satellite radio services via alternative media, most obviously
including terrestrial radio. Fewer than 10% of the 240 million U.S. automobiles in use contain
satellite radio receivers, while virtually all vehicles include AM/FM radios.14 Only
3.4% of radio listening is to satellite.15 More than 30 percent of Americans use MP3
players (including iPods) on a weekly basis, more than six times the
|
|
|
10 |
|
For example, see Federal Communications Commission, In the Matter of Application
of Digital Satellite broadcasting Corporation for Authority to Construct, Launch and Operate a
Digital Audio Radio Service Satellite System, Response of the National Association of Broadcasters
to Digital Satellite Broadcasting Corporations Opposition to Petitions to Deny and Response to
Comments, File Nos. 26/27-DSS-LA-93; IO/l I-DSS-P-93 (June 25, 1993), [NAB Response 1993], and
Federal Communications Commission, In the Matter of Request for Comment on Petition Filed by the
National Broadcasters Regarding Programming Carried by Satellite Digital Audio Radio Services,
Reply Comments of the National Association of Broadcasters, MB Docket No. 04-160 (June 21, 2004)
[NAB Response 2004]; http://www.nab.org/AM/AMTemplate.cfm?template=/CM/ContentDisplay.cfm&ContentID=3785. |
|
11 |
|
See case records at the Federal Communications Commission filings for MB Docket No.
07-57; http://www.fcc.gov/transaction/xm-sirius.html#record. |
|
12 |
|
J. Gregory Sidak, Expert Declaration of J. Gregory Sidak Concerning the Competitive
Consequences of the Proposed Merger of Sirius Satellite Radio, Inc. and XM Satellite Radio, Inc.
(March 16, 2007) [Sidak 2007]; http://ssrn.com/abstract=977318. The paper was
commissioned by the Consumer Coalition for Competition in Satellite Radio, an organization
supported by the National Association of Broadcasters (Ibid., p. 37). |
|
13 |
|
Kit Spring and John Wren, Satellite Radio Merger Attempt Likely, Based on History &
Risk/Reward, Stifel Nicolaus (Nov. 27, 2006), [Spring 2006], p. 2. |
|
14 |
|
Tim Farrar, The Competitive Landscape for Satellite Radio, Telecom, Media & Finance
Associates (April 6, 2007), [Farrar 2007]; http://www.tmfassociates.com/SatRadio.pdf. |
|
15 |
|
Arbitron study cited in Stifel Nicolaus, Thoughts About the Thinkable XM-Sirius
Merger: Expect Resistance, But Increasingly Doable Over Time, Washington Telecom, Media & Tech Insider (March 5, 2007), p. 1. |
8
|
|
|
|
|
|
Thomas W. Hazlett
|
|
The Economics of the Satellite Radio Merger |
number who listen to satellite radio.16 [A]lmost 50% of iPod users had purchased
accessories which allow for in-car connections, as per a January 2005 study.17 These
facts put the relevant firm positions into focus. The great majority of U.S. consumers substitute
from satellite to terrestrial AM/FM radio or other media each and every day.
The proposed merger combines two niche players in the radio market. It attempts to rationalize
industry structure, forging a superior competitor which, via efficiencies gained in operations and
finance, will offer an enhanced package of valuable services, improving its competitive thrust
against dominant terrestrial station incumbents and emerging digital media rivals.
II. RIVALRY AND ANTITRUST
It has been well reported that the XM-Sirius deal is strongly opposed by terrestrial
broadcasters, who have invested in an aggressive campaign to convince regulators to block the
merger. One such news report explains the situation thusly:
Former Attorney General John Ashcroft... has blasted Sirius Satellite Radio Inc.s
proposed acquisition of XM Satellite Radio Holdings Inc., saying the combination would
leave only one provider in the market. Ashcroft... was hired by the National
Association of Broadcasters to examine the acquisition... The NAB, which represents
traditional radio broadcasters, has been a fierce critic of the acquisition, now worth
about $4.4 billion, since it was announced last week.18
Perhaps the most telling piece of evidence as to the likely economic effect of the satellite
merger is found in this reaction by rival radio broadcasters. Their opposition signals precisely
what regulators attempting to discern pro-competitive from anti-competitive combinations need to
know: will the transaction result in higher outputs and reduced quality-adjusted prices? Dartmouth
economist B. Espen Eckbo explains the economic incentives at work:
[I]t is important to keep in mind that, while preventing efficient mergers harms
consumers, the rivals of the merging firms benefit as they avoid having to face
competition from an increasingly efficient merged firm. The rivals can indeed form a
politically strong interest group in situations
|
|
|
16 |
|
See Table 5, below. |
|
17 |
|
Farrar 2007, p. 2. |
|
18 |
|
Ashcroft Attacks Sirius-XM Deal,
Associated Press (March 2, 2007);
http://news.moneycentral.msn.com/ticker/article.aspx?Feed=AP&Date=20070302&ID=6565391&Symbol=AAPL. |
9
|
|
|
|
|
|
Thomas W. Hazlett
|
|
The Economics of the Satellite Radio Merger |
where they perceive a significant threat to their existing industry equilibrium.19
From the earliest days of the satellite radio industry indeed, years before the first
satellite was launched radio stations have seen the medium as a dangerous competitive threat. In
filings with the Federal Communications Commission and elsewhere, incumbent broadcasters have
consistently argued that the public interest in terrestrial radio is put at risk by satellite
operators siphoning off listeners.20
With the February 2007 announcement that satellite radio systems XM and Sirius had reached an
agreement to join forces,21 broadcasters again signaled just how serious they consider
this economic rivalry to be. They have attacked the combination as merger to
monopoly,22 and emphatically urge regulators to reject the merger as anti-competitive.
Radio station owners reveal precisely what one needs to know about the proposed merger between XM
and Sirius to evaluate its effect on consumer welfare.
Were the proposed combination truly anti-competitive, the post-merger satellite radio
enterprise would predictably raise quality-adjusted prices, reducing subscriptions sold. These are
the telltale signs of merger to monopoly. With fewer households purchasing satellite radio
service, more would be listening to terrestrial stations. Station owners would thereby enjoy
financial gains as their audiences and, hence, ad revenues, grew. Not only would this be profitable
for broadcasters, it would according to the broadcasters long-standing rationale for public
policy enhance the public interest.
In seeking to block the proposed XM-Sirius combination, however, terrestrial radio interests
reveal that they predict just the opposite would occur. They anticipate that a merger would
facilitate not price increases, but an intensification of rivalry. Economies of scale enabled via
merger could markedly improve the ability of XM and Sirius to lure subscribers from free radio. A
strategy to prevent this efficient market restructuring by obtaining regulatory intervention nicely
illustrates the anticompetitive use of competition policy.
In studies published by radio broadcasters and industry trade associations, it is argued that
the proposed merger would raise satellite radio prices by at least 5% for at least two
years.23 There are many problems with the analysis, as discussed below, but the thrust
of the broadcasters policy suggestion is most informative. Were the NAB to believe rivals prices
would substantially increase, it would unless subverting the interests of its members
enthusiastically support the merger.
|
|
|
19 |
|
B. Espen Eckbo, The Anticompetitive Significance of Merger Revisited, paper for
The Market for Corporate Control Regulation and Corporate Governance Issues, Univ. of Lille 2 (March 22, 2007), p. 14. |
|
20 |
|
NAB Response 1993, p. 4. |
|
21 |
|
XM 2007. |
|
22 |
|
Sidak 2007, p. 2. |
|
23 |
|
Sidak 2007, pp. 8-14. |
10
|
|
|
|
|
|
Thomas W. Hazlett
|
|
The Economics of the Satellite Radio Merger |
The testimony of industry incumbents is particularly powerful, in that radio stations have had
well over a decade to research the question of satellite competition. With about $82 billion in
station values, terrestrial broadcasters have strong incentives to pursue policies that will
protect their assets. Broadcasters took a leading position opposing a spectrum allocation for
satellite radio from the early 1990s on the rationale that competition with terrestrial stations
would hurt them:
[S]atellite DARS systems will immeasurably injure terrestrial radio stations by
siphoning off listeners with their thirty or more channels of new
programming.24
Since the auctioning of satellite radio licenses in 1997, the National Association of
Broadcasters (NAB) has aggressively lobbied for regulations that would limit the ability of XM or
Sirius to provide competitive services such as local news, weather, and sports, which reduce
terrestrial listening audiences:25
In lieu of the promised niche audiences... [XM and Sirius] have instead devoted
substantial bandwidth to compete directly with local broadcasters with local content,
without being subject to any public interest obligations... A centralized localized
service, which is essentially duplicative of existing programming, does little to
foster diversity and localism: it can only exist to the detriment of the dissemination
of free and over-the-air local services to local communities.26
See Appendix 1, NAB Statements on Terrestrial vs. Satellite Radio Competition, for a further
sampling of positions taken by broadcasters confirming their view that terrestrial and satellite
services are highly competitive.
A merger produces multiple economic effects. On one side, merging otherwise independent firms
can reduce the number of competitors, lessening market rivalry.27 On the other,
combining assets to foster cooperation in production can yield efficiencies, intensifying
inter-brand competition. The merger evaluation task carried out by pro-consumer policy agencies is
to discern where the factors in a given merger balance out: on net, and over time, will consumers
and the overall economy benefit?
In the satellite radio merger, this balancing test has been conducted by certified, reliably
self-interested experts in the matter. Terrestrial broadcasters have concluded that satellite radio
is a substitute for their product, and that a merger between satellite
|
|
|
24 |
|
NAB Response 1993, p. 4. |
|
25 |
|
Thomas Hazlett, Local Motives, Slate (March 16, 2004); http://www.slate.com/id/2097247/. |
|
26 |
|
Federal Communications Commission, In the Matter of Establishment of Rules and
Policies for the Digital Audio Radio Satellite Service in the 2310-2360 MHz Frequency Band Radio
Service Terrestrial Repeaters Network, National Association of Broadcasters Petition for
Declaratory Ruling, IB Docket No. 95-91 GEN Docket No. 90-357 (April 14, 2004), Executive Summary. |
|
27 |
|
The same can be said for contracts, joint ventures, or patent licensing agreements,
each of which are common, pro-competitive features of a capitalist economy. |
11
|
|
|
|
|
|
Thomas W. Hazlett
|
|
The Economics of the Satellite Radio Merger |
operators would enhance the attractiveness of that competitive alternative. Pre-empting this
combination would deny rivals critical efficiency gains, effectively raising rivals
costs.28 While clothed in the language of antitrust, the strategy is itself
anti-competitive.
III. CONSUMER IMPACT
Prof. J. Gregory Sidak, articulating the case for merger foes, defines the relevant
merger market as limited to two satellite radio operators, labeling the proposed combination a
merger to monopoly.29 This analysis claims that the market is not sufficiently
competitive to support the merger. On the contrary, Sirius CEO Mel Karmazin argues that there is
abundant choice available to listeners, including terrestrial radio, new HD stations, iPods, CDs,
Internet radio stations, and services delivered via mobile handsets.30
Courts and regulatory authorities grapple with the issue by examining various price and output
measures, along with consumer surveys and other evidence. What is a more fundamental point in any
competitive analysis, however, is that the burden of proof should not be on the marketplace. That
is to say, where increasing consumer welfare is the objective of public policy, the question is not
whether the market as defined one way or the other is sufficiently competitive. The
determinative policy cut is whether the proposed merger will likely increase or decrease the value
of services available to consumers.
This goes to the essential goal of competition policy: not to protect competitors, but
competition. This is a process that over time provides customers better products, lower
prices, and greater innovation. Individual competitors may or may not achieve that; when a merger
increases consumer benefits, then it is pro-competitive whatever the current market definition and
whatever regulators conclude about the extent of competition. Economist Kenneth Heyer of the U.S.
Department of Justice Antitrust Division articulates the point:
Over the past several decades, there has emerged a rough consensus among professional
antitrust practitioners, and within the law and economics community generally, that
the competition referred to in our antitrust statutes is not to be interpreted
simply as pre-merger rivalry
|
|
|
28 |
|
Thomas G. Krattenmaker and Steven C. Salop, Anti-competitive Exclusion: Raising
Rivals Costs to Achieve Power over Price, 96 Yale Law Journal 2 (Dec., 1986). |
|
29 |
|
Sidak 2007, p. 2. |
|
30 |
|
Mel Karmazin, Chief Executive Officer, Sirius Satellite Radio, Regarding the Digital
Future of the United States: The Future of Radio, Testimony Before the House Energy and Commerce
Committees Subcommittee on Telecommunications and the Internet (March 7, 2007);
http://energycommerce.house.gov/cmte_mtgs/110-ti-hrg.030707.karmazin-testimony.pdf. |
12
|
|
|
|
|
|
Thomas W. Hazlett
|
|
The Economics of the Satellite Radio Merger |
among entities. Rather, it is best viewed as a process, the outcome of which is
welfare, with welfare not rivalry being the object of interest.31
Arguments as to the relevant market and its competitiveness are secondary. The primary
consideration is whether a given transaction will benefit consumers and the economy.32 This focus is fundamental, as debates over many of the derivative questions may not admit to
easy resolution. Fortunately, in the satellite radio merger, the primary issue does. Precisely
because the combination is so clearly a threat to the dominant provider of radio broadcasting
services, it is clearly a competition-enhancing event.
The consumer benefits of the merger can be summarized as flowing from two broad sources. The
first stems from economically strengthening upstart competitors in radio broadcasting. Valuable
consumer options will be sustained, and new ones emerge, because satellite broadcasting
currently valued at less than the capital invested in the two existing platforms becomes more
financially viable. Market rivalry intensifies when costs of capital for satellite radio, now
extraordinarily high, are reduced, justifying innovation and product upgrades otherwise
unaffordable. And the more aggressive is the competition stemming from satellite radio providers,
the more likely it is that alternative providers will offer higher value to consumers in response.
The second category of consumer gains is associated with the direct benefits of lower cost
products and wider customer choice. With the proposed combination, subscribers will enjoy greater
scale economies in radio receivers and standardized technologies, and gain access to a wider array
of programming. Instead of making choices between popular channels carried exclusively by one
satellite system or the other, and then shouldering risks associated with changes in program menus
or their own preferences, customers will be able to confidently access their favorite shows.
A. Financially Strengthening Competitive Entrants into Radio
The argument for merger, in fact, has been made for some time by industry experts who
saw the financial weakness of satellite radio operators as a major impediment to robust inter-modal
rivalry between satellite and terrestrial radio. As Yahoo!Finance reported, most analysts see
numerous financial reasons to like a combined XM-Sirius:...33 Deutsche Bank projects
that a merged entity could generate $5bn in cost synergies,34 a forecast consistent
with other estimates.
Stifel Nicolaus, calling the merger a no brainer, estimates that a successful merger could
create $7 billion of shareholder value, a result produced under the assumption that prices to
consumers would not increase while product improvements
|
|
|
31 |
|
Kenneth Heyer, Welfare Standards and Merger Analysis: Why Not the Best? 2 Competition Policy International 2 (Autumn 2006) [Heyer 2006], p. 29. |
|
32 |
|
Heyer 2006 offers a compelling argument that a total welfare standard should rule merger analysis. |
|
33 |
|
Sonja Ryst, Analyst to XM, Sirius: Quit Quibbling, Yahoo! Financial News (Feb. 20, 2007); http://uk.biz.yahoo.com/20022007/244/analyst-xm-sirius-quit-quibbling.html. |
|
34 |
|
James G. Dix, The Die is Cast Reaffirm Buy Ratings on Merger, Deutsche Bank (Feb. 20, 2007), p. 1. |
13
|
|
|
|
|
|
Thomas W. Hazlett
|
|
The Economics of the Satellite Radio Merger |
would drive enhanced subscriber growth.35 Consensus forecasts of aggregate cost savings
due to merger synergies range from $3 billion to $7 billion in net present value.36
Table 1. Cumulative Deficits and Enterprise Values
for XM and Sirius, as of 2007 ($mil.)
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Cumulative Cash Flows |
|
|
Value of Deficit, |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
CFs invested at: |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Capital, |
|
|
|
|
|
|
U.S. |
|
|
12% |
|
|
Enterprise |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Operating & |
|
|
|
|
|
|
Treasury |
|
|
hurdle |
|
|
Value |
|
|
|
Sales |
|
|
Interest Expense |
|
|
Deficit |
|
|
Bills |
|
|
rate: |
|
|
|
|
Sirius |
|
|
1,910.0 |
|
|
|
7,620.3 |
|
|
|
-5,710.3 |
|
|
|
6,488.6 |
|
|
|
9,132.5 |
|
|
|
4,800.0 |
|
XM |
|
|
2,994.6 |
|
|
|
7,660.5 |
|
|
|
-4,665.9 |
|
|
|
5,147.4 |
|
|
|
7,158.9 |
|
|
|
4,420.0 |
|
|
|
|
Note: Cumulative sales and expenses through 2006 calculated from Sirius (1993-2007) and XM
(1998-2007) annual reports. Sales and expenses for 2007 projected in Moffett, Rifkin and Parker,
XMSR and SIRI: Heads I Win, Tails You Lose, Bernstein Research (April 23, 2007). T-bill returns for
2007 assumed to equal median annual return, 1992-2006. Enterprise values from Yahoo!Finance (June 8, 2007). |
Such efficiency gains are an attractive opportunity under any circumstances; in
satellite radio, such changes have the potential to dramatically advance competitive forces. Wall
Street sees satellite radio firms as financially constrained, given high capital costs and elusive
profitability. Markets currently establish an enterprise value (EV)equal to market value of
equity plus market value of debtof about $4.4 billion for XM and about $4.8 billion for Sirius,
or approximately $9.2 billion in aggregate. In contrast, the combined investments of the two firms,
including capital expenditures and operating losses through 2007, are valued at $11.6 billion,
assuming reinvestment at prevailing t-bill rates. When outflows are compounded at a more realistic
12% cost of capital (hurdle rate),37 the present value of expenditures rises to over
$16.3 billion. See Table 1. Substantially more money has been invested in satellite radio service
than firm owners and bondholders have to show for it.
This is inconsistent with steady-state equilibrium. The big picture, as revealed by market
valuations, is that investment is flowing out of satellite radio. The recurring investments
required for continued operations will be difficult to sustain; innovations to improve products and
expand services will be difficult to launch. These constraints have direct and important
consequences for consumer choice.
Owners and managers of firms, quite productively, look for ways to reorganize operations. This
realignment is crucial for consumer welfare, as it seeks to redeploy
|
|
|
35 |
|
Spring 2006, p. 1. |
|
36 |
|
XM 2007. |
|
37 |
|
RBC Capital Markets uses a hurdle rate for XM-Sirius of 10.8%; Bear Stearns a rate of 11.3%; Deutsche Bank 14%. |
14
|
|
|
|
|
|
Thomas W. Hazlett
|
|
The Economics of the Satellite Radio Merger |
assets in a way that creates competitive superiority. To the degree the firms are correct about
projected efficiencies, investment capital will flow into, rather than out of, satellite radio.
This will increase competitive options for current and potential customers.
By invigorating the satellite radio service, the merger offers to sustain and intensify the
inter-modal rivalry featured in the competition between terrestrial and satellite radio. According
to terrestrial broadcasters themselves, the presence of satellite radio service is a competitive
choice for listeners, some of whom will be siphoned to an alternative service.38 The
launch of digital HD radio by terrestrial stations has been explicitly ascribed by the National
Association of Broadcasters to satellite radios market entry.39 Some radio stations are
reducing commercial time in an effort to keep listeners from migrating to satellite.40
By increasing the probability that satellite radio will be viable for the long run, the value of
satellite radio as a competitive option increases.
|
|
|
38 |
|
NAB Response 1993, p. 4. |
|
39 |
|
Lockett 2004. |
|
40 |
|
Newman 2007. |
15
|
|
|
Thomas W. Hazlett
|
|
The Economics of the Satellite Radio Merger |
Table 2. Broadcaster Bond Ratings
41
|
|
|
Sector/Company (No. of bonds) |
|
Moodys / S&P Ratings |
|
Terrestrial Broadcasters |
|
|
Clear Channel Communications (16) |
|
Baa3 / B+ |
Emmis Communications Corp. (1) |
|
B3 / B- |
Entercom Communications Corp. (1) |
|
B1 / B |
Salem Communications Corp. (2) |
|
B2 / B- |
Radio One (2) |
|
B1 / B- |
Satellite Broadcasters |
|
|
Sirius (1) |
|
Caa1 / CCC |
XM (2 bonds with separate ratings) |
|
Caa3 / CCC- ; Caa1 / CCC |
Source: NASD BondInfo. Citadel, not shown here, has one unrated publicly traded bond. This
tabulation includes ratings for all bonds, regardless of maturity.
Part of this increase in competitiveness accrues from lower capital costs for entrants.
XM and Sirius have issued debt that is rated well below investment grade. This is not a result of
the firms balance sheets exhibiting extraordinarily high leverage.42 Table 2 shows
debt ratings for radio broadcast companies with publicly traded issues (Clear Channel, Emmis,
Entercom, Salem, Sirius and XM). The terrestrial broadcasters have ratings of medium grade
obligations or speculative. In contrast, the bonds of Sirius and XM are designated as having
poor standing.
Low ratings signal high risk, resulting in relatively high capital costs. Table 3 displays the
average yields for publicly traded, non-convertible bonds with at least two years to maturity
remaining. The yields-to-maturity on bonds of the two satellite companies exceed, by over 300 basis
points (3 percentage points), yields for bonds that make up a widely used index for medium-grade
corporate debt (Lehmans Triple B/Baa Index). In comparison, the debt of terrestrial broadcasters
trades at a much smaller discount to medium grade bonds, indicating that these broadcasters face a
more certain future and enjoy a lower cost of capital.
|
|
|
41 |
|
Moodys: Obligations rated Baa are subject to moderate credit risk. They are
considered medium-grade and as such may possess certain speculative characteristics... Obligations
rated B are considered speculative and are subject to high credit risk... Obligations rated Caa are
judged to be of poor standing and are subject to very high credit risk. Moodys Rating Symbols &
Definitions (March 2007), p. 8. Standard & Poors: Obligations rated BB, B, CCC, CC, and
C are regarded as having significant speculative characteristics. BB indicates the least
degree of speculation and C the highest. While such obligations will likely have some quality and
protective characteristics, these may be outweighed by large uncertainties or major exposures to
adverse conditions. Standard & Poors Credit Ratings; https://www.bonddesk.com/sp.html (visited
June 9, 2007). |
|
42 |
|
At market values, the ratio of debt to equity for XM = 0.41; Sirius ratio =
0.25. Yahoo!Finance (May 30, 2007). |
16
|
|
|
Thomas W. Hazlett
|
|
The Economics of the Satellite Radio Merger |
Table
3. Bond Yields for Radio Broadcasters (May 25, 2007)
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Risk Premium over |
|
|
|
Yields |
|
|
BBB corporate |
|
Bonds |
|
(% p.a.) |
|
|
( % p.a.) |
|
|
Terrestrial radio mean of 11 bonds from Clear
Channel, 5 bonds from Entercom, Radio One, and Salem |
|
|
7.12 |
|
|
|
1.05 |
|
Satellite radio 3 bonds form Sirius and XM |
|
|
9.09 |
|
|
|
3.02 |
|
US Corporate Debt Triple B / Baa (Lehman Index) |
|
|
6.07 |
|
|
|
0.00 |
|
Source: Broadcaster bonds NASD Bondinfo, most recent yield to May 25 in the Daily Summary,
http://www.nasdbondinfo.com. US Corporate debt from the Wall Street Journal, Markets Data Center,
Tracking Bonds Benchmarks; http://online.wsj.com/mdc/public/page/2_3022-bondbnchmrk.html
?mod=mdc_bnd_pglnk (visited May 25, 2007). Notes: All broadcaster bonds are non-convertible and
have remaining maturities of two years or more. The single traded Emmis bond is excluded because
it is convertible. All bonds are callable except one from Clear Channel and one each from Salem and
XM. Call features lower prices and raise yields.
The data indicate that satellite radio operators face very high capital costs, making it
difficult to sustain their recurring fixed investments or to undertake investment projects
including system upgrades, product innovations, or R&D that would be profitable at conventional
hurdle rates. Financial distress, in short, hampers a firms ability to compete. One influential
study found that firms with high leverage see their output decline more in downturns than the
average firm in their industry.43
Merger synergies, if realized, would predictably improve satellite radios financial position.
This would lower capital costs, making a range of product-enhancing investments more economical.
It would also, of course, raise the probability that a strong competitive presence challenging
terrestrial broadcasters and other audio media would continue and intensify.
B. Direct Gains for Consumers
Recognizing the dynamic nature of radio fundamentally undercuts the static analysis of
market share offered by broadcasters merger to monopoly claim, as shown in detail in Section V.
It also shows how important it is for consumers that new economies be realized. Merger is one
obvious and large source of such efficiencies, precisely why many independent analysts have
embraced the combination. With a stronger financial base, capital costs will decline. Moreover,
product choice will increase. And, most essentially, the long-run health of the competitive
entrants will improve, thereby raising the probability that terrestrial broadcasters will face this
important inter-modal rivalry for years to come. James Surowiecki writes in The New Yorker:
|
|
|
43 |
|
Tim C. Opler and Sheridan Titman, Financial Distress and
Corporate Performance, 49
Journal of Finance 1015 (July 1994). |
17
|
|
|
Thomas W. Hazlett
|
|
The Economics of the Satellite Radio Merger |
Consumers, then, have little to fear from a merged satellite company in the radio
market, and they may actually have a lot to gain. Dominated by chains like Clear
Channel, AM/FM radio has become a catalogue of bland choices, pre-programmed
playlists, and syndicated talk. A recent study by the Future of Music Coalition
found that four companies received fifty per cent of all radio advertising revenue
and had nearly fifty per cent of all listeners. Even among competitors, there is
often tremendous overlap in music playlists; in this environment, XM and Sirius,
which offer real diversity across three hundred channels, are a gain for consumer
choice. And theres no reason to think that this diversity would ebb after a
merger; no one wants to pay thirteen dollars a month to hear the same songs he
could have got free from his local KISS-FM.44
This take views the merger as pro-competitive in extending the strength of a small competitor
against the industrys dominant suppliers. Merger may prove particularly important for an entrant
into a business that involves high fixed costs relative to marginal costs, a situation applying to
XM-Sirius:
Not surprisingly in a new business where most costs are fixed rather than variable,
both firms still make losses. But this cost structure, rather than a desire to
increase market power, is what makes the deal attractive, says Craig Moffett of
Sanford C. Bernstein, a broker. By teaming up, the two firms can cut their fixed
costs, the biggest of which is content. A merger would cut the cost of Howard
Stern in half, says Mr Moffett, and so move the combined firm closer to profit. It
is unlikely, he contends, that the merged firm would raise prices beyond the
$12.95 per month that both Sirius and XM now charge subscribers.
But what about choice? Counter-intuitively, a merger would lead to more of it, say
XM and Sirius, since it would allow them to drop channels that duplicate each other
and to replace them with a wider range of niche channels.45
That the merger will increase the ability of the entrant to compete for market share is not
controversial. Broadcasters themselves endorse this view by objecting to the merger. That radio
stations are reacting, altering their investments and business models, reveals the competitive
threat posed by satellite radio and other media: While commercial radio stations once had
automobile drivers ears all to themselves, competition today is intense, writes the New York
Times. The satellite companies
|
|
|
44 |
|
James Surowiecki, Satellite Sisters,
The New Yorker (Mar 19, 2007); http://www.newyorker.com/ talk/financial/2007/03/19/070319ta_talk_surowiecki. |
|
45 |
|
They cannot be Sirius: Regulators may oppose the merger of Americas two satellite-radio firms, The
Economist (Feb 24, 2007), p. 73. |
18
|
|
|
Thomas W. Hazlett
|
|
The Economics of the Satellite Radio Merger |
Sirius and XM offer scores of noncommercial stations, and new cars are increasingly
factory-equipped to play iPods.46
This intense inter-modal competition is not centered on price. Given the rather disparate
pricing models of advertising-supported terrestrial broadcasting, subscription satellite radio, MP3
devices, and other emerging digital media, it is clear that the competitive frontier is largely
defined in terms of quality and convenience of service rather than price. Thomas Jorde and David
Teece note the confusion that results when static models are employed in such markets, with
analysts focusing only on nominal prices. In markets presenting these competitive dynamics the
test for substitution between products, informing market definition of the relevant antitrust
market, is then not appropriately conducted by merely analyzing prices.
When competition proceeds primarily on the basis of features and performance, the
pertinent question to ask is whether a change in the performance attributes of one
commodity would induce substitution to or from another. If the answer is
affirmative, then the differentiated products,
even if based on alternative technologies, should be included in the relevant
product market. Furthermore, when assessing such performance-induced
substitutability, a one-year or two-year period is simply too short, because
enhancement of performance attributes involves a longer time to accomplish than
price changes.47
This seriously undercuts the applicability of the SSNIP48 test, used for defining
antitrust markets, in the context of the satellite radio merger (see discussion below, in Section
V). Rather, it suggests that competition clearly encompasses multiple audio services, given that
the suppliers of the disparate services react (by their own admission) to the performance-enhancing
features of rivals. This identifies terrestrial and satellite radio as competitors, which by
itself places satellite radio in a safely competitive context. This is seen in Table 4, showing
the relative size of the service providers as measured by industry revenues.
|
|
|
46 |
|
Newman 2007, op cit. |
|
47 |
|
Thomas M. Jorde and David J. Teece, Antitrust Policy and Innovation: Taking Account
of Performance
Competition and Competitor Cooperation, 147 Journal of Theoretical and Institutional Economics 118 (1991), p. 124. |
|
48 |
|
SSNIP refers to a small but significant non-transitory increase in price, and is
used in defining antitrust markets. The exercise attempts to find the smallest set of products,
including the products of the parties to the proposed merger, that a monopolist would need to
control to profitably increase prices a small but significant amount above competitive levels.
Mary T. Coleman, David W. Meyer, and David T. Scheffman, Economic Analyses of Mergers at the FTC:
The Cruise Ships Mergers Investigation, 23 Review of Industrial
Organization 2 (Sept. 2003) [Coleman et al. 2003], p. 122. |
19
|
|
|
Thomas W. Hazlett
|
|
The Economics of the Satellite Radio Merger |
Table 4. U.S. Radio Broadcasting Revenues, 2000-2006 ($MIL)
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
2000 |
|
|
2001 |
|
|
2002 |
|
|
2003 |
|
|
2004 |
|
|
2005 |
|
|
2006 |
|
|
Satellite Digital Audio Radio Service |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
XM (1) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
0.5 |
|
|
|
20.2 |
|
|
|
91.8 |
|
|
|
244.4 |
|
|
|
558.3 |
|
|
|
933.4 |
|
Sirius (2) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
0.8 |
|
|
|
12.9 |
|
|
|
66.9 |
|
|
|
242.2 |
|
|
|
637.2 |
|
Total
Satellite |
|
|
|
|
|
|
0.5 |
|
|
|
21.0 |
|
|
|
105 |
|
|
|
311 |
|
|
|
801 |
|
|
|
1,571 |
|
|
Commercial Terrestrial Radio Broadcasters (3) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Network |
|
|
1,029 |
|
|
|
919 |
|
|
|
1,000 |
|
|
|
1,033 |
|
|
|
1,081 |
|
|
|
1,053 |
|
|
|
1,112 |
|
National |
|
|
3,596 |
|
|
|
2,898 |
|
|
|
3,275 |
|
|
|
3,470 |
|
|
|
3,453 |
|
|
|
3,384 |
|
|
|
3,553 |
|
Local |
|
|
15,223 |
|
|
|
14,552 |
|
|
|
15,134 |
|
|
|
15,100 |
|
|
|
15,479 |
|
|
|
15,634 |
|
|
|
15,478 |
|
Non-Spot |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
1,260 |
|
|
|
1,398 |
|
|
|
1,384 |
|
|
|
1,522 |
|
Total
Commercial |
|
|
19,848 |
|
|
|
18,369 |
|
|
|
19,409 |
|
|
|
20,863 |
|
|
|
21,411 |
|
|
|
21,455 |
|
|
|
21,669 |
|
Terrestrial |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Grand Total |
|
|
19,848 |
|
|
|
18,370 |
|
|
|
19,430 |
|
|
|
20,968 |
|
|
|
21,722 |
|
|
|
22,256 |
|
|
|
23,240 |
|
|
% Satellite |
|
|
N/A |
|
|
|
0.0 |
|
|
|
0.1 |
|
|
|
0.5 |
|
|
|
1.4 |
|
|
|
3.6 |
|
|
|
6.8 |
|
Sources: (1) XM 10-k filings; (2) Sirius 10-k filings; (3) Radio Advertising Bureau (RAB);
http://www.rab.com/public/pr/yearly.cfm. (RAB analysis includes information from Ernst Young, Radio
Expenditure Reports, Miller Kaplan & Arase Co., and Hungerford Aldrin Nichols & Carter.)
Even the tiny share of radio broadcasting sales accounted for by satellite radio just
6.8 percent as of 2006 diminishes when additional audio services are accounted for.
This reveals the presence of a wide array of popular, effective, and competitively priced
substitutes, rendering a satellite merger harmless. As the Financial Times notes:
[I]n the larger scheme of things, it matters little whether there is one US
satellite radio operator or two. Consumers have many alternatives if the merged
company throws its weight around: in a world with thousands of free internet radio
stations, tens of millions of iPods and countless unknown technologies on the
horizon, it is hard to see two companies with a combined 3 per cent market share as
a stifling monopoly.49
Given the range of consumer choice, a market restructuring to strengthen satellites position
over the long run serves pro-competitive ends. The way satellite services are marketed and sold
produces further gains from merger, as well. In the rivalry between XM and Sirius, different
content is offered by either system. This provides incentives to operators to pursue popular
content, but it also splits consumer purchases. With the merger of the two satellite platforms,
subscription to one service could allow a customer access to a broader range of popular
programming. These gains
|
|
|
49 |
|
Leader: Satellite Radio Merger Every Monopoly is not a Bad Monopoly in the iPod Age, Financial
Times (Mar 9, 2007), p.14. |
20
|
|
|
Thomas W. Hazlett
|
|
The Economics of the Satellite Radio Merger |
have impressed those
not normally disposed to endorse mergers, including the editors of
USA Today:
It makes little sense that sports fans must decide between every single pro football
game and no baseball games, or vice versa. Nor does it make much sense that peoples
listening preferences should enter into their car-buying decisions. Thats one
reason the proposed XM-Sirius combination, announced this week, may be the rare
merger that is good for consumers.50
The dynamic changes in the audio markets yield an analysis that is fundamentally distinct from
the static analysis offered by merger to monopoly. In the maelstrom of new services available to
listeners, satellite radio is hardly dominant, and clearly in need of seizing greater efficiencies
in order to offer long-run competitive value. These factors themselves combine to suggest that
only by pursuing the mergers market restructuring can satellite radio realize its potential as a
part of the emerging audio services market, a point made nicely in the Los Angeles Times:
Consider a few statistics. Half of the new cars sold in the U.S. this year will
have stereo systems designed to work seamlessly with an iPod. These and similar
devices can also play podcasts a recorded program that emulates over-the-air
radio from more than 44,000 sources. Of the roughly 12,500 over-the-air stations
pumping out conventional radio broadcasts, about 1,200 also broadcast in digital
frequently, with more than one channel in different formats. And a growing number
of mobile devices are able to tap into the expanding ranks of online music
services.
Meanwhile, Sirius and XM are bleeding money at a prodigious rate as they try to
amass the subscribers needed to overcome their debt and
depreciation costs. Allowing them to merge could save them billions of dollars in
marketing and maintenance expenses while preserving satellite radio as one of many
alternatives available to consumers.51
Finally, it is instructive that the investment community consensus views the XM-Sirius merger
as leading to between $3 billion and $7 billion in synergies, and does not anticipate gains from
price increases post-merger.52 Instead, analysts see the merger as an attempt by
satellite radio suppliers to drive costs down and to offer a more competitive product to customers.
The perceived strategy is to hold down prices while expanding product quality. Stifel Nicolaus
analysts project the merger will increase subscriber growth the combo will be able to offer
more programming by combining channels
|
|
|
50 |
|
Our View on Your Radio Options: Sirius and XM Together Makes Sense for Listeners, USA Today
(Feb. 23, 2007); http://blogs.usatoday.com/oped/2007/02/post58.html. |
|
51 |
|
Radio Daze, XM and Sirius, the nations two satellite radio providers, want to
merge. The FCC should let them.
Los Angeles Times (Feb. 20, 2007). |
|
52 |
|
XM 2007. |
21
|
|
|
Thomas W. Hazlett
|
|
The Economics of the Satellite Radio Merger |
leading to 1MM more
subs over time53 precisely the quality-adjusted price competition that benefits
consumers.
If these independent analytical assessments are accurate, and there is no evidence suggesting
they are not, than this assessment is dispositive. Transactions likely to expand output are
pro-competitive. A merger that reduces effective prices to subscribers and delivers billions of
dollars worth of cost saving efficiencies is in the public interest under either a consumer
welfare or a total welfare standard.
IV. SATELLITE RADIO COMPETITION
It is no secret that in merger reviews market definition essentially listing the
economically relevant rivals to the merger parties is often determinative. It is therefore
important to further elaborate on the issue of satellite radios market competition. This section
attempts to do that, covering three specific topics.
First, it establishes the historic rivalry between satellite radio and terrestrial radio as
evidenced in the long effort by radio broadcasters to obtain regulatory rules limiting the scope of
satellite radios product menu, broadcast quality, and competitiveness. Second, it analyzes Cable
TV v. Broadcast TV competition, an analogy introduced by Sidak, to explain how radio broadcasting
competes directly with satellite radio. While Sidak asserted that satellite and radio services do
not effectively compete, the example he raised supports just the opposite conclusion. Third, it
examines the current market for audio services, exploring the product mix that consumers consider
substitutes for satellite radio service. Evidence gleaned across all three discussions reveal that
terrestrial radio and satellite radio are strong inter-modal rivals and satisfy similar demands via
substitute products.
A. Historic Rivalry Between Satellite and Terrestrial Radio
Satellite radio, also known as satellite DARS (digital audio radio service) or SDARS,
was first considered by the FCC in 1990. Four firms filed petitions requesting spectrum
allocations, and a proceeding was opened to consider the applications. A contentious rule-making
took place that spanned seven years before the FCC successfully allocated 25 MHz of spectrum to two
DARS licenses (12.5 MHz each) and awarded them, via auction, for approximately $173 million in
April 1997.54
The long rule-making was largely consumed by a dispute over what harm satellite radio entry
would bring terrestrial radio stations. The National Association of
|
|
|
53 |
|
Spring 2006, p.4. |
|
54 |
|
See Federal Communications Commission, Auction 15 Digital Audio Radio Service
(DARS) Factsheet; http://wireless.fcc.gov/auctions/default.htm?job=auction_factsheet&id=15. |
22
|
|
|
Thomas W. Hazlett
|
|
The Economics of the Satellite Radio Merger |
Broadcasters (NAB) relentlessly fought the allocations, claiming that the introduction of satellite
broadcasting would deal a lethal financial blow to many terrestrial stations. See Appendix 1 for a
sample of these comments.
When outright denial faded as a policy outcome, the NAB put forth multiple requests for
regulatory burdens to be levied on the rival service. In this proceeding, and long before the
SDARS services had even launched, the broadcasters position was that satellite radio would
siphon55 listeners from terrestrial radio and reduce its revenues. That, the NAB
argued, would reduce the public interest in a healthy and vibrant local radio service. Whatever
the merits of that argument, the competitive position of terrestrial broadcasting was never in
doubt: broadcasters explicitly sought to block competition for broadcasters market share on the
grounds that such competition was harmful to society. A 1995 FCC Reply Comment filed by the NAB is
illustrative:
One way that the Commission can act to minimize the harmful effects of satellite
DARS introduction is to structure it as a subscription-only service, as the NAB has
proposed. Although satellite DARS will have a competitive impact on terrestrial
stations in every radio market no matter what its regulatory classification, the
NAB has urged the Commission to soften this blow to the greatest extent possible.
Canvassing the Commissions available regulatory options, a subscription
requirement will introduce at least some level of differentiation between satellite
DARS and terrestrial radio, and will help to minimize the direct impingement by
satellite DARS providers into markets for advertising sales.56
Lest there be any question about the reality of terrestrial-satellite radio rivalry, the NAB
elaborated in a footnote:
Whether it is advertising-supported or not, satellite DARS providers fundamentally
will compete with terrestrial broadcasters for listeners.
Because audience impacts are the primary driver in the radio business, smaller
audiences translate into reduced sales of advertising to both local and national
advertisers, notwithstanding DARS suppliers focus of subscriptions or national
advertisers for support.57
The footnote went on to cite a Kagan study:
|
|
|
55 |
|
Federal Communications Commission, In the Matter of Amendment of the
Commissions Rules with regard to the Establishment and Regulation of New Digital Audio Radio
Services, Comments of the National Association of Broadcasters, Gen. Docket No. 90-357 (Nov. 13,
1990), p. 17. |
|
56 |
|
Federal Communications Commission, In the Matter of Establishment of the Rules and
Policies for the Digital Audio Radio Satellite Service in the 2310 to 2360 MHz Frequency Band:
Reply Comments of the National Association of Broadcasters, IB Docket No. 95-91 (Oct. 13, 1995),
pp. 34-5 (footnotes omitted). |
|
57 |
|
Ibid, p. 34. |
23
|
|
|
Thomas W. Hazlett
|
|
The Economics of the Satellite Radio Merger |
Although subscriber supported services would not appear to propose a direct threat
to local broadcasters revenue base, the audience fragmentation likely to occur
from the deluge of programming options could severely handicap traditional radio
broadcasting...58
The competition that the NAB feared has materialized, according to numerous NAB Comments filed
with the FCC post-DARS entry. In a 2004 petition to the Commission, terrestrial broadcasters
sought a declaratory ruling that satellite operators could not offer local content even if
distributed nationwide. It stated the case that inter-modal competition was intense:
What was true in 1995 is still true today if SDARS is allowed to penetrate the
local market, local broadcasting, and the voice of the community it provides, will
suffer. Contrary to XM and Sirius assertions, the Commission did not reject the
1995 economic studies. Rather, the Commission stated that they because they [found]
no evidence that satellite DARS would be able to compete for local advertising,
terrestrial broadcasting would not be substantially harmed. The latest actions by
satellite radio providers step beyond the boundaries they promised to stay within,
to be a national service, and require the Commission to again look at the hard data
the NAB and others provided in 1995. With the addition of local traffic and
weather, satellite radio is no longer an exclusively national service; and its
impact on terrestrial broadcasting is growing and could quickly evolve into a force
in the local advertising market. How much harm, however, is largely dependent on
Commissions decision in this proceeding and timely FCC action.59
The FCC took no action, the NAB petition was withdrawn,60 and the competition that
the NAB feared rages on. Terrestrial broadcasters are not, of course, sitting idly by.
Continuing to see satellite radio as a competitive threat, in late 2005 the NAB launched a $40
million advertising campaign with spots that highlight... compelling audio entertainment on local
radio and close with the tag Radio: You Shouldnt Have to Pay for It.61 This
followed the launch of HD radio as a performance-based competitive response to satellite radio and
other audio products, and preceded the initiation of a $250 million advertising campaign to make
consumers aware of this competitive option.62
|
|
|
58 |
|
Ibid.
|
|
59 |
|
NAB Response 2004, pp. 15-16 (footnotes omitted, italics in original). |
|
60 |
|
NAB Withdraws Petition to FCC on Satellite Radio, Radio Currents
Online (Nov. 10, 2004); http://radiomagonline.com/currents/radio_currents110804/. |
|
61 |
|
National Association of Broadcasters, Radio Industry Launches New On-Air Ad
Campaign, Press Release (Nov. 30, 2005);
http://www.nab.org/AM/Template.cfm?Section=Press_Releases1&
CONTENTID=5170&TEMPLATE=/CM/ContentDisplay.cfm. |
|
62 |
|
HD Radio Launching $250 Million Ad Campaign,
Orbitcast (Dec. 4, 2006);
http://www.orbitcast. com/archives/hd-radio-launching-250-million-ad-campaign.html. |
24
|
|
|
Thomas W. Hazlett
|
|
The Economics of the Satellite Radio Merger |
B. The Cable TV and Broadcast TV Analogy
Prof. Sidaks Declaration offers a telling example, using the regulatory history of
cable television to offer insight on the proper way to view competition between radio stations and
satellite radio operators.63 The episode is important, in that it reveals how
regulatory authorities have viewed rivalry between free (advertising support) services delivered
over the air by broadcasters and an alternative delivery system selling subscription services
including much larger channel packages with much more diverse programming. The implications for the
XM-Sirius merger are, as Sidak indicates, pronounced. But they are the opposite of what his
analysis offers.
Sidak writes that the 1992 Cable Act recognized that the broadcast medium could not
effectively compete with the emerging and popular multichannel subscription-based
services...64 He cites the Acts finding that, without the presence of another
multichannel video programming distributor, a cable system faces no local
competition.65 This is correct. The 1992 statute allowed local authorities to cap
cable rates, under FCC guidelines, except in markets where effective competition was found to
exist. This term was defined in the statute to involve head-to-head competition with another
multi-channel video provider such as a cable TV operator, a satellite TV operator, or a
multi-channel, microwave distribution system (MMDS).
Sidaks analysis is also correct in its interpretation that the statute nominally omitted
broadcast television as a relevant competitor. The medium was, by 1992, believed to offer only a
weak constraint on cable TV pricing in most markets, but not everywhere. In fact, the 1992 Cable
Act explicitly defined effective competition as obtaining in a cable TV market when less than 30%
of households subscribed to the service.66 This implicitly included broadcast TV and
other video delivery systems in the
market. Moreover, it means that if the 1992 Cable Act rules delineating competition between free
and subscription services were applied to radio, it would today produce the conclusion that
satellite radio does not constitute a separate market but is effectively competitive with
alternative media including terrestrial radio. Satellite radio with 14 million subscriptions in
a nation of over 110 million households and 240 million automobiles falls well below the 30%
effective competition threshold, however calculated.67 Table 5, showing results of a
recent audio listenership study by Bridge Ratings, indicates that only about five percent of U.S.
citizens listen to satellite radio on a weekly basis, as compared to over 93 percent who listen to
terrestrial stations. Hence,
|
|
|
63 |
|
See Sidak 2007, pp. 22-25. |
|
64 |
|
Ibid, p. 22. |
|
65 |
|
Ibid. |
|
66 |
|
See Thomas W. Hazlett and Matthew L. Spitzer, PUBLIC POLICY TOWARDS CABLE TELEVISION: THE ECONOMICS OF RATE CONTROLS (MIT Press, 1997) [Hazlett & Spitzer 1997], p. 62. |
|
67 |
|
Given the very low penetration of satellite radio, an exact measure is here
unnecessary. Yet, it should be noted that probably fewer than ten percent of households subscribe
to satellite radio today, as many of the 14 million SDARS subscriptions are delivered within family
plans. It is also the case that multiple subscriptions are generally needed per household to fully
substitute for terrestrial broadcasting, counting listening time in cars, home and work. |
25
|
|
|
Thomas W. Hazlett
|
|
The Economics of the Satellite Radio Merger |
Sidaks regulatory reference, properly constructed, offers direct evidence for the notion that
satellite radio operates in a market that is effectively competitive with rival media.
TABLE 5. PERCENTAGE OF AMERICANS USING AUDIO MEDIA (WEEKLY)
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Satellite |
|
Internet |
|
|
|
|
|
|
HD Radio |
|
Radio |
|
Radio |
|
MP3 Players |
|
AM/FM |
May 2007 |
|
0.0015 |
|
4.8 |
|
21.0 |
|
30.4 |
|
93.7 |
June 2006 |
|
0.0010 |
|
4.6 |
|
19.0 |
|
30.1 |
|
93.5 |
Source: Population Break-Down of Audio Listenership, ORBITCAST (May 29, 2007)
(reporting survey by Bridge Ratings);
http://www.orbitcast.com/archives/population-breakdown-of-audio-listenership. html.
The history of cable TV offers additional support. In 1992, cable television had become
the dominant delivery platform for video services, with 55.2 million subscribers out of a universe
of 93.2 TV households (for a penetration rate equal to 59.2 percent).68 Cable was
perceived to be changing from an inter-modal rival to TV broadcasting into a market of its own. It
was additionally seen that broadcast TV signals, which are carried by cable TV systems and which
are typically of higher signal quality over cable, were losing their effectiveness as substitutes.
Hence, the 1992 Act reversed a policy enacted when cable TV penetration was lower. In 1984,
with cable TV systems emerging as an important video delivery platform, the first national Cable TV
Act was enacted. In that measure, the federal government pre-empted local rate regulation in any
market where effective competition
existed. The term was then defined by the Federal Communications Commission, in April 1985, to
obtain wherever three or more over-the-air TV stations (Grade B contours) were
available.69 In 1991, the FCC revisited the question, increasing its effective
competition standard to the presence of six over-the-air TV signals.70
In 1992 the Congress redefined effective competition in cable TV markets further. Cable TV
had gone from a fledgling competitor to dominance among delivery platforms. The shift altered
market definition.
The relevance for the XM-Sirius merger is that satellite radio is today fledgling, not
dominant. The services are considered substitutes, and the great majority of
|
|
|
68 |
|
Kagan, Cable TV Financial Databook (June 1991), p. 11; Cable TV Financial Databook 1997, p.7. |
|
69 |
|
We now conclude that the existence of three or more off-the-air broadcast signals
in the cable market provides viewers with adequate programming choices and presents an effective
constraint on the market power of a cable system in the provision of basic service. Federal
Communications Commission, In the Matter of Amendment of Parts 1, 63, and 76 of the Commissions
Rules to Implement the Provisions of the Cable Communications Policy Act of 1984: Report and Order,
MM Docket No. 84-1296 (rel. Apr. 19, 1985), at 32-33. |
|
70 |
|
Federal Communications Commission, In the Matter of Reexamination of the Effective
Competition Standard for the Regulation of Cable Television Basic Service Rates: Report
and Order and Second Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, MM Docket No. 90-4 (rel. July 12,
1991), par. 1. |
26
|
|
|
Thomas W. Hazlett
|
|
The Economics of the Satellite Radio Merger |
customers currently choose substitutes over subscription satellite radio. The pre-1992 effective
competition standards in cable TV explicitly recognized this type of rivalry. Even when applying
the 1992 statutory cable rules Sidak cites, satellites market penetration is sufficiently low as
to be considered effectively competitive with inter-modal rivals. Hence, the cable TV example is
apt. Alternative media effectively constrain the behavior of subscription satellite service
providers.
C. Competition in Audio Services
Developments in technology have dramatically broadened the choices
available... [for] audio programming. By the late 1990s, consumers had the newfound
ability to listen to audio streamed over the Internet, and two new radio
satellite services were born. Digital radio has continued to evolve with the
advent of podcasting... and HD Digital Radio... In the past, radio was limited
solely to what was available on the AM/FM dial. Today radio choices for consumers
appear to have no bounds.71
Terrestrial and satellite broadcasting compete for customers. The terms of this rivalry are
not the textbook perfect competition margins where identical firms with identical products
compete on price, instantly converging to identical prices via the pressure of perfect
substitutability.72 The dynamics of this real world marketplace force rivals to
innovate and to differentiate, precisely as broadcasters are doing in adopting digital technologies
to produce HD digital radio.73
In a dynamic sense, the audio services market is swimming with competition. The primary issue
regarding adoption of alternative services is distribution of customer premises equipment (CPE).
The embedded base of investment in receiver/player units is a barrier for new technologies to
surmount, as competitive services typically require adoption of new CPE. This is certainly true of
satellite radio, HD radio, iPods and other MP3 players.74 CDs and cassettes, as well as
AM/FM radio receivers, are already well
|
|
|
71 |
|
Arbitron, The Infinite Dial 2007: Radios Digital Platforms [Arbitron, 2007];
http://www.arbitron.com/downloads/digital_radio_study_2007.pdf, p.1. |
|
72 |
|
Former Federal Trade Commission Chair James Miller, now a consultant to the NAB,
argues against the XM-Sirius merger by quoting the FCC: Other audio delivery media are not, of
course, perfect substitutes for satellite (radio). That is not surprising, as differentiated
products do not perfectly substitute; firms compete largely by adding features that distinguish
their products. Millers invocation of perfect substitutes as the standard for whether other
products are included in the same market, however, actually renders the satellite radio merger
harmless. Given that XM and Sirius are not perfect substitutes, they would occupy separate markets
under the Miller analysis. The merger would, thus, have no impact on market concentration. James
C. Miller III, Satellite Radio Merger: How Sirius? WASHINGTON TIMES (May 1,
2007); http://washingtontimes.com/commentary/20070430-093354-5176r.htm. |
|
73 |
|
That HD is terrestrial broadcasters competitive response to satellite radio is
evidenced by the testimony of broadcasters themselves (see Lockett 2004, op cit.), and is obvious
to outside observers: iBiquity launched its digital radio technology at CES in 2004... The big
difference between iBiquitys digital radio and the popular services from XM and Sirius is that
iBiquitys digital signals are broadcast from the stations you already know and love, over the
traditional AM and FM bands. And its free, just like todays ordinary radio. Ordinary Radio
Strikes Back, CNET NEWS.COM (Jan. 6, 2005). |
|
74 |
|
Currently, 30% of Americans age 12 and over own a portable MP3 player. Arbitron
2007, op cit., p. 3. |
27
|
|
|
Thomas W. Hazlett
|
|
The Economics of the Satellite Radio Merger |
distributed among potential listeners, mitigating switching costs. Cellular phones are also
widely distributed, given over 230 million U.S. mobile phone subscribers,75 with more
and more handsets featuring MP3 capability76 or AM/FM radio tuners.77
In the maelstrom to establish a base of customers equipped to receive the content they
distribute, all these media compete on multiple price and performance margins. Crucial aspects of
rivalry are not captured in standard static models focused solely on price competition. But they
form virtually the entire whole of what is interesting and competitive about the market for audio
services.
A recent essay in PC MAGAZINE78 states the case in an
informative way. The writer sees satellite radio as existing in a space where wireless internet
delivery (IP) is emerging as the dominant distribution platform. This is seen in the emergence of
cellular and local area wireless networks for accessing audio content. The use of such services is
today modest, compared with traditional radio broadcasting, in the same way that satellite radio
penetration is today modest relative to terrestrial broadcasting. But the confines of that market
with its substitutability across audio products are already visible. The author of the
article listens to AM/FM, satellite radio, and his iPOD, all of which are available to me in my
car. But on long trips, he uses his EV-DO-connected laptop to play Internet radio stations, using
a Rhapsody web application, through his car speaker system. Noting a wireless WAN connection...
[yields] media choices... beyond what I could have ever imagined three short years ago, the writer
sees a rich and diverse
content universe being supplied by a variety of IP networks and devices. The implications for
XM-Sirius are drawn:
If the NAB thinks it has competition now from this proposed satellite merger,
imagine what type of competition it will face when wireless IP content becomes
mainstream and gives consumers more choices then they could ever dream of. The NAB
will look back at this period in history and reminisce about a time when it only
had to deal with satellite competition. Ah, the good old days.
So, while the FCC, Justice Department, and Congress review the proposed XM and
Sirius merger and consider the issue of consumer choices, I
|
|
|
75 |
|
The Cellular Internet and Telecommunications Industry Association (CTIA)
reported 238,006,530 subscribers as of June 8, 2007; http://www.ctia.org/. |
|
76 |
|
Music services via handsets are provided by cellular carriers Cingular, Verizon
Wireless, and Sprint Nextel. Stifel Nicolaus, Cingular Online Music Moves Impact Satellite Radio
Antitrust Analysis, WASHINGTON TELECOM, MEDIA & TECH INSIDER (Nov. 3. 2006), p. 6. |
|
77 |
|
Bridge Ratings latest study of cell phone use shows that 25% would really like to
use their cell phones to time-shift on-demand radio content, while 30% see listening to some form
of radio content on their phones as a service of interest. Only 8% were interested in audio
streaming through their cell phone, but 37% use it for music downloading and 15% as an AM/FM
receiver. Bridge Study Says Cell Phones Threaten Radio Listening, RADIO ONLINE
(May 9, 2007); http://news.radio-online.com/cgi-bin/$rol.exe/headline_id=b9879. |
|
78 |
|
Tim Bajarin, Would a Sirius/XM Merger Violate Consumer Rights?, PC
MAGAZINE (March 16, 2007); http://www.pcmag.com/article2/0,1895,2104518,00.asp. |
28
|
|
|
Thomas W. Hazlett
|
|
The Economics of the Satellite Radio Merger |
respectfully submit that they put their concerns through my video/media jukebox in
the sky litmus test. If they do, and fully understand the ramifications of
wireless changing everything, it would be hard to rule against this mergerat
least when it comes to the argument that it limits consumer choices.79
This broad view of the market is compelling. Analysts evaluating market trends and the
competitiveness of rival firms see burgeoning competition in audio services. One such review, by
Standard & Poors, notes vibrant rivalry across platforms:
Music phones and wireless music services have become immensely popular. US wireless
subscribers with music playerenabled cell phones grew from 4.6 million in the
third quarter of 2005 to 23.5 million in the same quarter in 2006... More than two
million subscribers downloaded music over the air to their phones in the third
quarter of 2006... (p. 19).
The percentage of wireless subscribers who purchase music over cellular networks
will grow from 4% in 2006 to 21% by 2010, based on studies by IDC (p.
20).80
To apply standard equilibrium models of market structure to an industry that features such
volatility is to invite overly conservative assessments of the margins on which rivalry exists. As
shown in the following section, that is precisely the error rendered in characterizing the
satellite combination as merger to monopoly.
V. SIDAKS MERGER ANALYSIS
In the most ambitious analysis of the XM-Sirius merger offered by opponents, Georgetown
University Law Professor J. Gregory Sidak defines a critical elasticity measure, evaluates market
shares, and examines net consumer benefits. He concludes that satellite radio constitutes the
most reasonable market definition, and that the XM-Sirius combination would constitute merger to
monopoly. Even a broader market definition including terrestrial broadcasters would rule the
merger anti-competitive, asserts Prof. Sidak, who uses the metric of radio channel capacity to
measure market share. Finally, Sidak sees only small (gross) consumer benefits accruing from
merger in that the forecast synergies accrue, by his calculations, almost entirely to fixed costs
reductions rather than to marginal cost savings.
|
|
|
79 |
|
Ibid. |
80 |
|
Standard & Poors, Industry Surveys: Telecommunications Wireless (March 22, 2007). |
29
|
|
|
Thomas W. Hazlett
|
|
The Economics of the Satellite Radio Merger |
These conclusions are unwarranted. Sidaks own analysis, ironically, produces a strong
defense of the merger. This is so for the following reasons.
1) |
|
Sidak calculates a critical own-price elasticity of demand for the post-merger
firm81, and then argues that satellite radio features an own-price demand
elasticity below the critical level (in absolute value), such that a 5% price increase for
the merged entity would be profitable. But the market Sidak claims to define has
negative capital value, suggesting that no sustainable, long-term satellite radio service
let alone stand-alone market yet exists. Moreover, duopoly or monopoly markets
should exhibit above-competitive profits. Hence, the lack of expected profitability is a
fatal flaw in the market definition analysis. |
|
2) |
|
Sidak claims that the most reasonable market definition includes simply XM and
Sirius, but then considers other competitive media, including HD radio and, then,
terrestrial radio. Market shares are measured not using revenues or units sold, but radio
channel capacity. This methodology would show, e.g., that no antitrust issue would arise
were Clear Channel to purchase 80% of U.S. radio stations by revenue, so long as they only
owned just 20% of terrestrial stations. It
would also, conversely, eliminate any antitrust issue with the XM-Sirius merger by simply
including Internet radio, with its vast channel capacity. Using revenue shares, as in
standard analyses, terrestrial radio stations and networks dwarf satellite radio, with 2006
sales of over $21 billion vs. just $1.6 billion. These more appropriate market shares
reveal that there is only trivial change in industrial concentration via the XM-Sirius
merger. |
|
3) |
|
In evaluating evidence as to the own-price elasticity for satellite radio demand,
Sidaks key empirical evidence suggesting low elasticity is that when, in April 2005, XM
hiked monthly service prices by 30% it encountered (according to Sidak) virtually no
reduction in subscriber growth.82 This is said to establish price elasticity
of demand below the critical level, revealing satellite radio to be a distinct
market.83 The conclusion is incorrect. Sidaks analysis actually defines XMs
service as a distinct market. If true, this renders an XM-Sirius merger |
|
|
|
81 |
|
Miscalculates, actually. Given his model and factual assumptions, the correct
calculation of critical own-price elasticity is -1.43, less (in absolute value) than Sidaks
derivation of -1.52. Sidaks equation [2]
defines price elasticity of demand as:
ε = [Q1/Q0]÷[P1//P0] given the constant elasticity assumption.
However, this
is an incorrect approximation. The critical own-price elasticity of demand can still be calculated
without indeed resorting to the constant elasticity assumption, with Sidaks assumed price and
margin, using the original elasticity formula:
ε
=[(Q1 - Q0)/Q0]÷[(P
1 - P0)/P0]=[Q1
/Q0
- 1]÷[P1/P0 - 1].
Sidak, further makes an incorrect simplication going from Equation [3] to Equation [4]:
the logarithm of the product
1.05 ε should be
ln(1.05) + ln( ε ) , not ε ln(1.05) |
|
82 |
|
Sidak 2007, pp. 11-12. |
|
83 |
|
The empirical assertion by Sidak is here taken at face value. In an actual
assessment of elasticity, of course, one would compare the rate of subscriber growth change before
and after the price increase, and take into account other factors including the existence of
contracts. |
30
|
|
|
Thomas W. Hazlett
|
|
The Economics of the Satellite Radio Merger |
|
|
competitively harmless. While that policy conclusion is correct, it is not because XM and
Sirius occupy different markets. This outcome vividly illustrates the overly-narrow market
definitions Sidaks analytical framework produces. |
|
4) |
|
Sidak cites the 1992 Cable Act where cable TV competition was defined in terms of
available multi-channel video (cable, satellite) choices, using the analogy to establish
that over-the-air broadcasting is not considered a competitive constraint for subscription
services.84 The analogy is apt but demonstrates just the reverse. The 1992
Act specifically defined cable markets as effectively competitive when they served fewer
than 30% of homes passed, a threshold condition easily met by satellite radio services
today. Moreover, prior to 1992, when cable had yet to become the dominant distribution
platform for video, FCC regulators explicitly defined effective competition as the
presence of three (and, later, six) over-the-air TV stations. This non-dominant position is where subscription radio is today, and it
likewise competes with broadcasters for market share. |
|
5) |
|
Sidak finds consumer gains from the merger not to be substantial, only a 1.1%
reduction in marginal costs. This is a faulty approach both theoretically and
empirically. Factually, the consensus of independent market analysts predicts that a
merger would produce cost synergies of between $3 billion and $7 billion.85
Sidak assumes that these enormous efficiencies will not flow to consumers, by restricting
his analysis to exclude key competitive considerations such as product quality
improvements, technology upgrades, and economies of scale the very reasons compelling
investors to support the merger. In fact, independent analysts predict that the merger
will lower quality-adjusted prices for consumers, leading to increases in subscriber
growth due to efficiencies entirely ignored in the Sidak analysis. |
A. The Critical Own-Price Elasticity Model
Prof. Sidak pursues a critical own-price elasticity analysis to address the issue of
whether the merging parties collectively form a distinct product market. This method estimates a
critical elasticity of demand measure using the Lerner Index, a microeconomic formula derived
using price-marginal cost margins. The critical value indicates the level of substitutability for
services; if actual elasticity for the product of the post-merger satellite radio firm is predicted
to be less than this level, in absolute value, the merged firm is expected to have the incentive
and ability to raise prices five percent for a sustainable period. Claiming that the critical
elasticity = -1.52,86 Sidak proceeds to argue that the actual demand for satellite radio
is less elastic, leading him to conclude that (a) satellite radio constitutes a distinct product
market, and (b) merger will lead to higher consumer prices.87
|
|
|
84 |
|
Sidak 2007, pp. 22-23. |
|
85 |
|
XM 2007. |
|
86 |
|
Sidak 2007, p. 10. |
|
87 |
|
Ibid, pp. 11-14. |
31
|
|
|
Thomas W. Hazlett
|
|
The Economics of the Satellite Radio Merger |
There are several deficiencies in this approach and the conclusions obtained, numerical errors
aside. For one, there is no measurement of the actual, purportedly low, elasticity, and therefore
nothing to specifically compare to the critical elasticity. For another, the evidence cited to
estimate the actual elasticity, such as the churn rates, is derived from current pre-merger demand
for XM and Sirius products.88 No allowances are made for the high-growth, disequilibrium
circumstances of the satellite radio market, which are known to alter pricing strategies and,
hence, Lerner Index results.89 Moreover, the complexities of that marketplace, including
two-year customer contracts, exclusive contracts with automobile manufacturers, switching costs for
existing (and renewing) satellite radio customers, and switching costs for existing terrestrial
radio customers, are all ignored. This renders the analysis of firm pricing behavior incomplete, in
that each factor has a substantial impact on how consumers react to price increases.
B. An Asserted Duopoly Market with Negative Profits
If satellite radio constitutes a distinct market, it is today structured as duopoly.
Indeed, Sidak suggests just this. He approvingly quotes Gerald Faulhabers description of the
satellite merger: Its a duopoly looking to merge into a monopoly.90 Later, he refers
to current rates charged by XM and Sirius as the duopoly price.91
Sidaks market definition omits a crucial element: the cross-check provided by capital
markets. If a distinct market exists, it would feature non-negative profitability. Indeed, were
such a market organized as a duopoly headed, via merger, towards monopoly, expected profits would
be well above competitive levels. Indeed, the SSNIP test Sidak outlines and attempts to conduct is
designed to define the smallest set of products, including the products of the parties to the
proposed merger, that a monopolist would need to control to profitably increase prices a small but
significant amount above competitive levels.92 Where prices fail to generate
competitive returns, no market has been defined.
As seen above, however, XM and Sirius are valued at just about $4.4 billion and $4.8 billion,
respectively. These enterprise values include the market value of both equity and debt, and
represent the present value of all future earnings anticipated for the firms. Each firm has
invested significantly more than its EV, when capital expenditures and operating losses are
calculated in present value terms. All told, XM and Sirius have collectively spent upwards of
$11.5 billion. When cash flows are re-invested at the
|
|
|
88 |
|
Ibid, pp. 12-13. |
|
89 |
|
In this exercise, Sidak assumes that pre- and post-merger marginal costs are the
same, a dubious approach in a nascent industry where larger scale (say, through merger) may well
reduce marginal costs. It is also true that market dynamics, including strategic efforts to
establish the popularity of a new service, often render pricing predictions produced by the Lerner
formula incorrect. See, e.g., Robert Pindyck, The Measurement of Monopoly Power in Dynamic Markets,
28 Journal of Law & Economics 1 (Apr., 1985). |
|
90 |
|
Sidak 2007, p. 5. |
|
91 |
|
Ibid., p. 55. |
|
92 |
|
Coleman et al. 2003, p. 122. |
32
|
|
|
Thomas W. Hazlett
|
|
The Economics of the Satellite Radio Merger |
firms cost of capital (assumed =12%), the present value of expenditures for the two firms
exceeds $16 billion. See Table 1 in Section III.
These capital market valuations demonstrate that investors do no expect either the current
structure of satellite radio services, or the merger to monopoly, to produce monopoly profits.
Given the level of investment required to supply these services, other products are sufficiently
substitutable that not even competitive profits are anticipated. This renders the market defined by
Sidak illusory, and explains why the owners of assets providing satellite radio services would
logically seek new organizational forms in an attempt to gain profitability.
C. Defining Markets Narrowly: XM Doesnt Compete with Sirius
Prof. Sidak asserts that the most reasonable market definition would include only XM
and Sirius radio, such that the proposed transaction constitutes merger to monopoly. His model to
justify this conclusion is the critical own-price elasticity test, explained above. There is a
fatal flaw in the logic, however.
To establish that the actual price elasticity of demand for satellite radio services is below
that of the critical elasticity, Sidak cites the price increase instituted by XM in 2005:
On April 2, 2005, XM increased its monthly price from $9.99 to $12.95 to bring its
price in line with the price of Sirius an increase of nearly 30 percent. In the
two quarters following the price increase, XM realized subscriber growth of 13
percent (third quarter 2005) and 20 percent (fourth quarter 2005). The fact that
subscriber growth continued at such a rapid pace in the presence of [a] 30 percent
price increase underscores the low elasticity of demand faced by SDARS
providers.93
Calling this direct evidence on the own-price elasticity of demand faced by SDARS
providers,94 it is the only direct evidence offered. In the model used by Sidak it
proves far too much, however. Because XM raised prices and purportedly found only limited consumer
substitution away from its product, Sidaks analysis on its own terms demonstrates that the
market is defined as XM alone. Therefore, combining XM with Sirius does not increase industry
concentration and cannot be anti-competitive.
This stunning result falls out of the application of Sidaks framework to a market not in
long-run equilibrium, complex in terms of contractual mechanisms, and facing numerous inter-modal
rivals that compete primarily on quality.95 None of these
|
|
|
93 |
|
Sidak 2007, pp. 11-12 (footnotes omitted). |
|
94 |
|
Ibid, p. 12. |
|
95 |
|
It may also stem from a downward bias in Sidaks calculation of elasticity. In
failing to examine changes in the growth trend, or to account for other influences on
subscribership (apart from the increase in the monthly service fee), consumer price responses may
have been overlooked. |
33
|
|
|
Thomas W. Hazlett
|
|
The Economics of the Satellite Radio Merger |
complicating factors is taken into account in the analysis, which places XM and Sirius in
separate markets. The Sidak framework then, reveals little about real-world competition for audio
services, but produces compelling evidence that its own market definitions are too narrowly
crafted.
D. Market Shares by the Channel Capacity Metric
Relaxing the monopoly satellite radio market definition, Sidak then considers
including just HD radio as a competitor to satellite radio. This exercise in line drawing raises
several points. First, having been openly declared a competitive response to SDARS by
broadcasters,96 that this medium would be excluded under any market definition is
curious. Second, HD radio is a fledgling audio service that, following a launch in
2004,97 is being introduced station by station. Given the comparatively wide use of
still other audio products, including MP3 players, cellular audio services, and Internet radio, it
is ad hoc to include just this one inter-modal rival.
Indeed, broadcasters themselves stress repeatedly that a variety of digital audio media now
exist as direct rivals to terrestrial and HD radio. See, for instance, a sample of broadcasters
statements filed with the Securities and Exchange Commission, in Table 6. Citadel Broadcasting Corporation explicitly cites the XM-Sirius merger as a competitive threat:
The growth of Internet radio and the proposed merger of the two satellite radio companies, if
approved, could result in increased competition .98
In comparing HD radio stations market share with satellite radio, Sidak elects to use number
of channels to measure relative economic size. According to this methodology, if there were 20 HD
radio stations in a given geographic market, while Sirius delivers 133 channels and XM
170,99 then the satellite merger would constitute a 94% market share, HD in aggregate
just six percent. Sidak defends the use of channel capacity, citing the Department of Justices
Merger Guidelines that recommend using such an approach whenever capacity represents the best
indicator of the firms future competitive significance.100 Yet Sidak presents no
such evidence, and such an approach here is critically flawed.
First, it omits the vast content capacity of MP3 players, Internet radio, or other audio
products. Were capacity the proper measure of future competitive significance and not revenues or
other economic measures, the vast channel capacity offered by these media options would be of key
significance. Indeed, it is asymmetric to evaluate competition on the basis of capacity and to then
exclude capacious market segments. Second, the approach produces implausible policy conclusions.
This can be seen by means of a simple example. Suppose that the top seven radio stations in a
market
|
|
|
96 |
|
Lockett 2004. |
|
97 |
|
Digital Radio Makes Debut With CD-Quality Sound, CNN Technology
(Jan. 7, 2004); http://www.cnn.com/2004/TECH/ptech/01/07/digital.radio.ap/. |
|
98 |
|
See Table 6. |
|
99 |
|
These are the satellite radio channel sizes given in
Sidak 2007, p. 38. |
|
100 |
|
Sidak 2007, p. 37. |
34
|
|
|
Thomas W. Hazlett
|
|
The Economics of the Satellite Radio Merger |
featuring 35 individually-owned stations accounted for 80% of the markets ad sales and
listener ratings. The acquisition of these assets by one buyer would undoubtedly provoke an
antitrust response by authorities. Yet, it would muster no interest under Sidaks approach to
market share, even assuming Sidaks baseline assessment that terrestrial broadcasting is a separate
market from satellite radio. In this hypothetical merger, the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index (HHI)
would increase from 286 to 629, levels classified as unconcentrated, beginning to end, by the
DOJ/FTC Merger Guidelines.
In comparing channel shares between HD radio and satellite radio, Sidak purports to
demonstrate that satellite radio has overwhelming dominance and that a merger would be highly
anti-competitive. In his third and final pass at a market definition, however, Sidak offers to
include terrestrial and satellite radio together in one market. Not only is this competitive
rivalry apparent to the broadcasters, who are lobbying diligently to thwart the combination, but
also to independent observers. As investment analysts at Stifel Nicolaus comment:
Consider a world without terrestrial radio; what would that do to satellite radios
pricing power? We suspect it would increase it substantially. If so, then satellite
and terrestrial radio are probably in the same market.101
No matter. Using Sidaks market share metrics, terrestrial competitors change little. With 303
channels, the satellite providers again prove dominant, given that even a relatively large market
features no more than about 30 analog radio stations. As Sidak notes: Because the existing
capacity of analog signals is small relative to the merged firms capacity, and because the
ownership of such signals is mildly concentrated, the results are not significantly different from
those reported when defining the market to include just HD and SDARS. 102
Suffice it to say that this interpretation of the HHI merger analysis is unrealistic. In place
of competitively misleading channel numbers, an appraisal of rival economic size is called for.
The standard metric used in merger analysis is revenues. As seen above in Table 4, terrestrial
radio revenues in 2006, at over $21 billion annually, dwarf satellite radio sales of $1.6 billion.
Together, XM and Sirius account for less than 7% of radio revenues. This reverses the market share
comparison offered by Sidak: instead of terrestrial radio being one-tenth the size of satellite
radio in a typical (large) market with about 30 radio stations, it is over ten times larger than
satellite radio.
|
|
|
101 |
|
Stifel Nicolaus, XM-Sirius: Closer to a Toss-Up Than on Life Support; Focus on
FCC, Hearings, DBS Appears Off Mark to Us, Washington Telecom, Media, Tech Insider (May 2, 2007), p. 3. |
|
102 |
|
Sidak 2007, p. 40. |
35
|
|
|
Thomas W. Hazlett
|
|
The Economics of the Satellite Radio Merger |
Table 6. Radio Station Owners SEC 10K Statements About Competition For Audio Services
|
|
|
Clear Channel
Communications
|
|
New Technologies May Affect Our Broadcasting Operations Our broadcasting businesses face increasing competition from new
broadcast technologies, such as broadband wireless and satellite television and radio, and new consumer products, such as portable
digital audio players and personal digital video recorders. These new technologies and alternative media platforms compete with our
radio and television stations for audience share and advertising revenue, and in the case of some products, allow listeners and viewers
to avoid traditional commercial advertisements. ... Other matters that could affect our broadcast properties include technological
innovations and developments generally affecting competition in the
mass communications industry, such as direct broadcast satellite
service, the continued establishment of wireless cable systems and low power television stations, streaming of audio and video programming
via the Internet, digital television and radio technologies, the
establishment of a low power FM radio service, and possible telephone
company participation in the provision of video programming service. (2006 Annual Report, p.25) |
|
|
|
Beasley Broadcasting
|
|
The radio broadcasting industry also competes with other media technologies such as satellite-delivered digital audio radio services,
audio programming offered by cable systems, direct broadcast satellite systems, internet content providers, personal communications
services and other wireless digital audio delivery services as well as low-power FM radio, which has resulted in new noncommercial
FM stations serving small, localized areas. (2006 Annual Report, p. 6) |
|
|
|
Cumulus Media
|
|
In addition, the radio broadcasting industry is subject to competition from services that use new media technologies that are being
developed or have already been introduced, such as the Internet and satellite-based digital radio services. Such services reach
nationwide and regional audiences with multi-channel, multi-format, digital radio services that have a sound quality equivalent to that
of compact discs. Competition among terrestrial-based radio stations has also been heightened by the introduction of terrestrial digital
audio broadcasting (which is digital audio broadcasting delivered through earth-based equipment rather than satellites). (2006 Annual
Report, p.7) |
|
|
|
Citadel Broadcasting
Corporation
|
|
Competition: We operate in a highly competitive industry. Our radio stations compete for audiences and advertising revenue directly
with other radio stations as well as with other media, such as broadcast television, newspapers, magazines, cable television, satellite
television, satellite radio, the Internet (and Internet radio), outdoor advertising and direct mail within their respective markets. Our
radio stations also face increasing competition from new consumer products such as portable digital audio players, which create new
ways for individuals to listen to music and other content of their own choosing without traditional commercial advertisements. The
growth of Internet radio and the proposed merger of the two satellite radio companies, if approved, could result in increased
competition. [Latter emphasis added.] (2006 Annual Report, p. 26) |
|
|
|
Emmis
Communications
|
|
We must respond to the rapid changes in technology, services and standards that characterize our industry in order to remain
competitive. The radio broadcasting industries are subject to rapid technological change, evolving industry standards and the
emergence of competition from new media technologies and services. We cannot assure you that we will have the resources to
acquire new technologies or to introduce new services that could compete with these new technologies. Various new media
technologies and services are being developed or introduced, including: satellite-delivered digital audio radio service, which has
resulted in the introduction of new subscriber-based satellite radio services with numerous niche formats; audio programming by
cable systems, direct-broadcast satellite systems, personal communications systems, Internet content providers and other digital audio
broadcast formats; MP3 players and other personal audio systems that create new ways for individuals to listen to music and other
content of their own choosing; in-band on-channel digital radio (i.e., HD digital radio), which provides multi-channel, multi-format
digital radio services in the same bandwidth currently occupied by traditional AM and FM radio services; low-power FM radio,
which could result in additional FM radio broadcast outlets... (2006 Annual Report, pp. 18-19) |
36
|
|
|
Thomas W. Hazlett
|
|
The Economics of the Satellite Radio Merger |
Other economic measures of relative size all point in the same direction. XM and Sirius
jointly had an enterprise value of $9.2 billion on June 8, 2007, for instance. At the same time,
Clear Channel Communications radio broadcasting assets alone had an enterprise value of $13.7
billion.103 EVs for all terrestrial radio companies, based on a multiplier applied to
revenues, amount to about $82 billion. XM and Sirius, jointly account for just 10% of that total.
Employment levels present even a more lopsided picture. XM and Sirius have 860 and 772 employees,
respectively. Total employment by terrestrial and satellite radio broadcasting in 2006, in
contrast, was 113,482. Thus, the two satellite operators accounted for only 1.4% of market
employment. See Table 7. By any reasonable measure, including terrestrial broadcasting in the
relevant market when evaluating the XM-Sirius merger reveals the combination to encompass but a
small portion of radio broadcasting.
Table
7 Comparative Enterprise Value, Revenue
and Employment at Radio Stations And Xm-sirius104
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Enterprise Value |
|
2006 Revenue |
|
2006 |
|
|
June 8, 2007 (millions) |
|
(millions) |
|
Employees |
|
|
|
Pure-play publicly
traded
terrestrial broadcasters |
|
$ |
9,303 |
|
|
$ |
2,453 |
|
|
|
|
|
Clear Channel |
|
$ |
26,340 |
|
|
$ |
7,070 |
|
|
|
30,900 |
|
All terrestrial
broadcasters |
|
$ |
82,170 |
|
|
$ |
21,669 |
|
|
|
111,850 |
|
XM & Sirius |
|
$ |
9,220 |
|
|
$ |
1,571 |
|
|
|
1,632 |
|
Total Industry |
|
$ |
91,390 |
|
|
$ |
23,240 |
|
|
|
113,482 |
|
XM & Sirius as percent of total terrestrial &
satellite |
|
|
|
|
All broadcasters |
|
|
10.0 |
% |
|
|
6.8 |
% |
|
|
1.4 |
% |
Notes: Pure-play publicly traded terrestrial broadcasters include: Beasley, Citadel, Cox
Radio, Cumulus, Entercom, Radio One, Regent, and Salem. This groups EV/Revenue equals 3.79. Clear
Channel data apply to all of Clear Channel, which derived 52% of its 2006 revenues from radio
broadcasting. Clear Channels EV/Revenue equals 3.73. The enterprise value of all terrestrial
broadcasters ($82.17 billion) is estimated by applying the pure-play multiple of 3.79 to 2006
terrestrial broadcasting revenues ($21.7 billion). Source: Yahoo!Finance.
|
|
|
103 |
|
This measure counts 52% of Clear Channels total EV, which is the percentage of its
revenues derived from over the air radio broadcasting. |
|
104 |
|
Data for publicly traded stations for May 20, 2007 come from Yahoo!Finance
http://biz.yahoo.com/p/724conameu.html. Total terrestrial radio revenue from Radio
Advertising Bureau http://www.rab.com/public/pr/yearly.cfm. Total radio
broadcasting employees (except Internet) are from May 2006 National Industry-Specific Occupational
Employment and Wage Estimates, Bureau of Labor Statistics, NAICS 515110 Radio Broadcasting;
http://www.bls.gov/oes/current/naics5_515110.htm. Clear Channel, XM and Sirius employees from Google
Finance. |
37
|
|
|
Thomas W. Hazlett
|
|
The Economics of the Satellite Radio Merger |
E. A Static Model
1. Quality Enhancement
The static analysis used by Prof. Sidak omits consideration of whether the XM-Sirius merger
could lead to product improvements that increase value for consumers. Focusing solely on what he
identifies as marginal cost decreases and a hypothetical decrease in post-merger demand elasticity,
the analysis is on its own terms incomplete. That is because it leaves unanswered whether
asserted post-merger price increases would be compensated by quality enhancements leaving consumers
better off.
This is a severe omission. In theory, there is no reason to suspect that the sole source of
consumer gain springs from marginal cost reductions that reduce nominal prices. Competition among
audio service media, in fact, heavily relies on performance improvements among differentiated
products as opposed to price rivalry among homogeneous goods. This, many economists note,
fundamentally alters the competitive analysis.105 Even without complex theorizing, it is
apparent that the merger will permit an expansion of attractive programming choices for satellite
radio customers. Howard Kurtz, writing in the Washington Post, summarized this position by citing
an opinion offered in the blogosphere:
One of the frustrations of being a Sirius subscriber was that I always wondered if
I picked the right company. Since much of their premiere content is mutually
exclusive. I knew subscribing to Sirius meant I would not get any of the good
content from XM. So while it sounds like it will take about a year for their
programming to merge, it is nice to know I that eventually I will have the best of
both worlds.106
To combine the most popular listening options in the short-run, and to expand program line-ups
with the dual capacity of multiple systems (and bandwidth) as new receivers are developed over
time, leads to three sources of quality enhancement. First, it provides customers with a
higher-quality package on existing receivers, as the most popular programs can be transmitted to
all satellite radio subscribers. Second, it creates a path for line-up expansion over time. As new
receivers are available, additional programming content can be developed to fill extra channels,
leading to more diverse choices for customers. The technology and equipment standards to enable
this choice-expanding process will itself be facilitated by common ownership of satellite radio
assets post-merger. Third, merger reduces the risk that consumers associate with a satellite radio
receiver purchase. Solving the quandary confronting potential subscribers (cited above) with more
certain access to a diverse array of programs encourages technology adoption.
|
|
|
105 |
|
See, e.g., David J. Teece and Mary Coleman, The Meaning of Monopoly: Antitrust
Analysis in High-Technology Industries, The Antitrust Bulletin 801 (Fall-Winter 1998), [Teece & Coleman 1998] pp. 827-28. |
|
106 |
|
Howard Kurtz, Satellite Synergy, Washington Post (Feb. 21, 2007) (quoting Kings Chronicles);
http://www.washingtonpost.com/wp-dyn/content/blog/2007/02/21/BL2007022100354_pf.html. |
38
|
|
|
Thomas W. Hazlett
|
|
The Economics of the Satellite Radio Merger |
These gains are excluded from Sidaks static model. Consider the situation wherein
quality changes are the only consumer benefits i.e., where the advantages of the merger are
wholly contained in improved products for customers. There is no economic case to be made that
such mergers lack the ability to bring social gains. But the Sidak model would reject the merger by
simply excluding the benefit side of the ledger.
In reality, many experts see the merger as mainly about performance enhancements. Craig
Moffett of Bernstein Research, considering the opposition of terrestrial broadcasters to the
proposed combination, concludes that the position is largely driven by concern over program content
upgrades:
The NABs concern appears to be that a merged satellite radio company would have
less duplicative programming, and therefore could use its freed-up capacity to
offer more unique channels than the two companies have today. Specifically, they
would likely use at least some of the freed-up capacity for launching local-like
services such as local news (these kinds of services are permissible for satellite
radio under FCC rules as long as they are made available nationally rather than
locally). Ironically, the companies will undoubtedly argue to the FCC that greater
diversity of programming enabled by the same elimination of duplicative stations
and music genres is the single strongest public interest argument in favor of
the merger.107
Omitting quality from the merger analysis results in forecasts of competitive damage where, in
fact, large consumer gains are available. A mechanical application of the SSNIP test is known to
produce such results, which is why it is properly expanded to include additional evidence of market
definition and merger effects, particularly in emerging high-tech industries where new products
struggle to rival, or displace, established technologies. There, firms are likely to battle for
market share by non-price improvements and by exploiting economies of scale that, as in the
standard case of declining unit costs, spread fixed costs over larger production runs. Hence,
neither nominal prices nor predicted marginal cost changes reveal the essential efficiencies
delivered by the economic process.
By assuming that products in a market are homogeneous and competitors compete on price,
write David Teece and Mary Coleman,
[a]pplication of the SSNIP test in an industry where
competition is performance-based rather than purely price-related is likely to create a downward
bias in the definition of the size of the relevant product market, and a corresponding upward bias
in the assessment of market power.108 So here.
|
|
|
107 |
|
Bernstein Research, XMSR and SIRI: Where to From Here? (Feb. 20, 2007), p. 4
(emphasis in original). |
|
108 |
|
Teece & Coleman 1998, pp. 827-28. |
39
|
|
|
Thomas W. Hazlett
|
|
The Economics of the Satellite Radio Merger |
2. Dynamic Competition
Dynamic competition to develop new products and to improve existing products can
have much greater impacts on consumer welfare than static price competition, and
antitrust policy should take dynamic competition into account when evaluating
mergers or conduct in innovation-intensive industries.109
Prof. Sidak, assuming a constant pre- and post-merger product, and asserting that the only
marginal cost savings flow from billing costs (excluding customer acquisition charges from marginal
cost, e.g.), offers that just $10 million in annual marginal cost savings are associated with the
merger.110 These synergies, just 1.1% of what Sidak identifies as annual marginal
costs, produce Sidaks verdict that the majority of efficiencies identified by the merging parties
would not benefit consumers.111
This approach fails to consider marginal cost reductions for such items as customer
acquisition and customer equipment. More broadly, it is not true that the only gains that accrue to
consumers are short-run marginal costs. Indeed, the DOJ/FTC Merger Guidelines explicitly note that
antitrust authorities reviewing mergers consider the effects of cognizable efficiencies with no
short-term, direct effect on prices in the relevant market.112 Moreover, the Guidelines
recommend that productive efficiencies, should be considered as potential merger
gains,113 despite the fact that they are not likely to be measurable for the marginal
unit sold.
What is the magnitude of Sidaks efficiency omissions? Abstracting from quality enhancements
and focusing only on cost savings, the consensus view of independent investment analysts identifies
$3 billion to $7 billion in net present value (NPV) gains.114 RBC Capital Markets
explains their financial breakdown of the merger this way:
Our analysis suggests NPV of potential merger synergies in the $5-6 billion range,
though most would likely be realized 3-5 yrs. from now. While significant
realizable synergies exist, the most valuable synergies will not likely materialize
until longer-term OEMs (who wont have two entities to play off each other anymore)
contracts expire. We believe that back office, retail incentives, and advertising
savings are possible near-term, but only advertising synergies will likely drive
the same order of magnitude in savings as reductions in OEM and content costs.
Also, given
|
|
|
109 |
|
Richard J. Gilbert, New Antitrust Laws for the New Economy?, Testimony
Before the Antitrust Modernization Commission, Washington, D.C. (Nov. 8, 2005), p. 1. |
|
110 |
|
Sidak 2007,
p. 51. |
|
111 |
|
Ibid, p. 50. |
|
112 |
|
Horizontal Merger Guidelines, Department of Justice and the Federal Trade
Commission (April 2, 1992; Revised April 8, 1997) [Merger Guidelines], footnote 37. |
|
113 |
|
Ilene Knable Gotts, The Role of Efficiencies in Integrated Merger Analysis, DOJ
Presentation (Feb. 19, 2004); http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/workshops/docs/202669.htm. |
|
114 |
|
XM 2007. |
40
|
|
|
Thomas W. Hazlett
|
|
The Economics of the Satellite Radio Merger |
2-3 year OEM planning cycle, XM/SIRI probably need to maintain
separate operating platforms for 24 months post-deal. 115
These savings have been annualized in the consensus Wall Street view at about
$500 million.116 Now consider Sidaks claim that the total cost savings via merger sum to
$115 million per year, with just $10 million per year in marginal cost reductions.117 These estimates are cited from a web article, 118 and displayed in Sidaks Table 3, which,
he writes, shows the purported merger-specific savings that have [been] claimed by the
merging parties. 119
But these are not, in fact, the estimates of the XM and Sirius. The merging parties
cite analysts forecasts that NPV savings will range from $3 billion to $7 billion. 120
Indeed, the source referenced in Sidaks paper notes that the estimates are its own, and
that they exclude programming costs [which] are the largest expense at both
companies. 121 Nonetheless, this forms the source of Sidaks empirical assertion that
total savings from merger would amount to $115 million, of which just $10 million
would result in lower marginal costs and thus (solely) impact consumers.
Sidaks approach is incomplete, and its incompleteness on the cost efficiency
side can be quantified. In its most generous light, Sidaks cost savings estimate of
$115 million per year excludes 77% of the cost savings seen in the consensus estimate.
In addition, Sidak excludes pro-competitive effects of the increase in operator capacity
that would accrue from doubling the post-merged firms bandwidth, from gains in wider
distribution of existing content exclusive to only one of the operators, from better
coordination and pricing of satellite receivers and pre-sales auto installations (OEMs) or
programming, and from reduced customer acquisition costs due to economies of scale
and standardization in radio receiver production.
Further, the position that only marginal cost reductions create consumer gains is
incorrect. To an economist, the claimed efficiency must reduce the merged firms
marginal costs, as reductions in fixed costs do not affect the pricing decisions of a profit-maximizing firm. 122 Sidak thereby excludes, for instance, radio receiver price
reductions from any contribution to consumer welfare. The Merger Guidelines are cited
for support ... marginal cost reductions may reduce the merged firms incentive to
|
|
|
115 |
|
RBC Capital Markets, Wedding Bells are Ringing for XMRS and SIRI (Feb. 20, 2007), p. 28. |
|
116 |
|
Wachovia Equity Research, Sirius Satellite Radio (April 30, 2007), p. 1. As a
perpetuity discounted at
ten percent, $500 million annually is worth $5 billion in NPV, the mid-point of the consensus synergies
estimates. |
|
117 |
|
Sidak 2007, p. 51. |
|
118 |
|
Douglas McIntyre & Jon Ogg, How Sirius & XM Would Look As a Merged Company,
24/7WallStreet.com (Feb. 19, 2007), [McIntyre & Ogg 2007]; http://www.247wallst.com/
2007/02/how_sirius_xm_w.html. |
|
119 |
|
Sidak 2007, p. 51. |
|
120 |
|
XM and Sirius to Combine in $13 Billion Merger of Equals, XM Press Release (Feb. 19, 2007);
http://xmradio.mediaroom.com/index.php?s=press_releases&item=1423. |
|
121 |
|
Douglas McIntyre and Jon Ogg, How Sirius & XM Would Look As a Merged Company,
24/7WallStreet.com (Feb. 19, 2007); http://www.247wallst.com/2007/02/how_sirius_xm_w.html . |
|
122 |
|
Sidak 2007, pp. 50-51. |
41
|
|
|
Thomas W. Hazlett
|
|
The Economics of the Satellite Radio Merger |
elevate price.123 But this passage, while economically compelling, pointedly does
not support the analytical framework used.
Indeed, the Merger Guidelines explicitly invite consideration of fixed cost savings and the
creation of economies of scale,124 tempering unconvincing results yielded by simplistic
models of static equilibrium. Reductions in fixed costs, specifically costs that do not vary
directly with output, are essential to the creation of production economies, quality enhancements,
product innovation, and the creation of new entrants. In standard models of industrial structure,
such costs help determine the number of competitors, such that lowering fixed costs increases the
intensity of inter-firm rivalry. To assert that fixed cost economies provide no positive impetus to
consumer welfare is tantamount to denying that intellectual property rights, or policies that allow
for the recoupment of sunk investments, deliver important consumer benefits.
Whether additional firms can obtain FCC licenses to mimic the satellite radio delivery system
is an interesting regulatory issue.125 While it is a dynamic entry question that the
Sidak analysis selectively addresses, satellite radio licenses are one of many vehicles that can be
used by entrants into audio services. The launch of two SDARS networks has expanded market entry
by provoking the HD radio response from terrestrial broadcasters.126 Terrestrial
stations have also reduced commercial minutes in an effort to better compete with satellite
operators, who offer scores of commercial-free music channels.127 And the creation of
additional programming on a given satellite platform supplies competitive entry via expanded
choices for consumers.
Economies of scale can generate crucial consumer benefits, even as such social gains are
excluded by assumption in static models. With increased financial ability and economic incentives
to deploy advanced technologies, or standardized technologies, consumer benefits are generated.
With greater profitability available to marginal service providers, firms potentially reduce capital costs. This makes the investments necessary to supply
competitive satellite radio services more economical.
William J. Baumol writes that the process of continuous innovation by firms is the essential
ingredient of capitalist economic development.128 The pressure to recover continuing
and repeated sunk costs is its day-to-day driver.129 This quest for productive and
innovative efficiency, and the profit payoff for which investors risk capital to create it,
preserves and extends market rivalry. The static efficiency properties, writes
|
|
|
123 |
|
Merger Guidelines, supra note 9, at § 4, cited in Sidak 2007, footnote 175. |
|
124 |
|
Antitrust authorities analyzing mergers will also consider the effects of
cognizable efficiencies with no short-term, direct effect on prices in the relevant market.
Merger Guidelines, footnote 37. See also, Heyer 2006; and William Kolasky, Prepared Remarks,
FTC/DOJ Joint Workshop on Merger Enforcement Panel on Efficiencies/Dynamic Analysis/Integrated
Analysis, Washington D.C. (Feb. 19, 2004). |
|
125 |
|
Originally, four firms filed FCC petitions to obtain satellite radio licenses, and
the FCC initially allocated 50 MHz for four 12.5 MHz licenses. |
|
126 |
|
Lockett
2004, op cit. |
|
127 |
|
Newman 2007, op
cit. |
|
128 |
|
William J. Baumol, The Free Market Innovation Machine (Princeton
University Press, 2002). |
|
129 |
|
Ibid., p. 167. |
42
|
|
|
Thomas W. Hazlett
|
|
The Economics of the Satellite Radio Merger |
Baumol, ...are emphatically not the most important qualities of capitalist
economies.130 And his reference to the process of innovation well describes the
dynamics of satellite radio, where entrants have risked substantial investments to provide a new
range of products to customers, challenging old business models:
[I]n key parts of the economy the prime weapon of competition is not price but
innovation... [M]anagements are forced by market pressures to support innovative
activity systematically and substantially, and success of the efforts of any one
business firm forces its rivals to step up their own efforts. The result is a
ferocious arms race among the firms in the most rapidly evolving sectors of the
economy.131
This entrepreneurial dynamic is not powered by incremental reductions in marginal costs for
given technologies or services, but by the creation of new markets or products altogether. In
attacking radio broadcasting incumbents with a higher quality alternative, and in restructuring the
supply of satellite radio to strengthen this foray, the managers of XM and Sirius endeavor to
compete in this arms race. Yet that central event in the strategic alignment of XM-Sirius plays no
role in Prof. Sidaks analysis.
By common sense, the $5 billion in consensus savings has far more to do with the economic
purpose of the proposed merger than the $10 million in annual billing cost savings which forms the
sole merger rationale for consumers in Sidaks static model. Consumers are not insulated from the
enormous organizational and financial efficiencies that the merging parties seek to achieve. This has not escaped notice anywhere outside of static
models that foreclose such considerations. Indeed, broadcaster opposition to the merger is largely
based on just these expected outcomes:
The economic logic of the merger is irrefutable. These are, after all, very high
operating leverage businesses, with very high fixed and very low variable
costs. As a consequence, scale is tremendously important (this, too, suggests that
the companies are unlikely to raise prices as a consequence of greater market
power even after the merger, should it be approved).132
Broadcasters anticipate that the merger will make consumers more likely to listen to satellite
radio, and enjoy it. This is the pro-consumer aspect of the merger and the synergies that may be
largely ascribed to fixed costs.
|
|
|
130 |
|
Ibid., p. viii. |
|
131 |
|
Ibid., p. ix. |
|
132 |
|
Bernstein Research, Where to From Here? (Feb. 20, 2007), p. 5. Analyst Craig Moffett
elaborates the price constraint point: |
|
|
|
Strategy 101 would seem to dictate that sustained rapid
subscriber growth (i.e. a low price strategy) would easily trump harvest (i.e. a high price
strategy) for as long as possibly feasible. Moreover, since a merger would leverage these same high
fixed costs much more efficiently across a larger base, yielding a lower per-subscriber cost
structure, one could imagine that a merger would facilitate lower rather than higher consumer
rates. |
43
|
|
|
Thomas W. Hazlett
|
|
The Economics of the Satellite Radio Merger |
VI. CONCLUSION
Mergers and divestitures are a vital part of the process by which capital markets
rationalize the use of economic assets. When firms capture efficiencies, either by combining or
splitting up, investors realize positive returns. Often these gains derive from lower costs for
systems and operations, enabling the supply of more attractive products. Customers benefit
directly, facing lower quality-adjusted prices. They also benefit over time, as economies
intensify competitive forces, introducing improved products and expanded choices and, in turn,
provoking innovation from rivals.
The role of competition policy is to challenge acquisitions driven by the creation of market
power. Where a corporate sale is best explained as an effort to facilitate output restriction,
raising quality-adjusted prices, regulatory authorities have the ability to block it. The analysis
focuses on a balancing test in which the gains anticipated from merger synergies are weighed
against expected losses due to enhanced market power.
The XM-Sirius merger is well informed, in this balancing test, by the extremely large
efficiencies forecast by independent analysts, by the implausibility of quality-adjusted price
hikes post-merger, and by the strong opposition to the satellite radio combination by the services
chief inter-modal rival, terrestrial radio.
Consensus estimates by investment analysts see cost synergies of between $3 billion and $7
billion in net present value. These enormous efficiencies, equal to about half the aggregate
enterprise value of XM and Sirius combined, would bolster the financial position of competitive
radio entrants. This strengthens rivalry by raising its long-term prospects, permitting more
aggressive investment in satellite systems and products, and in prompting competitive responses
from terrestrial broadcasters and other competitors. Indeed, HD digital radio has already been
launched to counter satellites digital audio service.
Given the incentives of the merged satellite radio firm to expand its subscriber base, and
facing alternative audio media that include not only analog and HD broadcasting but MP3 players,
Internet radio, and cellular phones featuring both MP3 and AM/FM tuner technology, the competitive
constraints are tight. The merger is seen not as an attempt to restrict output, but as an effort to
strengthen the product, offering consumers more content per dollar. Analysts forecast that revenue
will increase post-merger not with price increases, but quality enhancements triggering higher
subscriber growth.
To view the merger as facilitating market power, a position taken by merger foes who define
the market as limited to satellite radio, conflicts with the economic evidence. Yet static models
omit this evidence, failing to incorporate non-price competition, technological innovation,
contracts, and the competitive role played by recurring fixed
44
|
|
|
Thomas W. Hazlett
|
|
The Economics of the Satellite Radio Merger |
costs. Simplistic application of such models produces implausibly narrow markets,
defining XMs product, for instance, as existing in a separate market from Sirius.133
The opposition of terrestrial broadcasters evinces no such analytical infirmity. Radio station
owners have long studied the issue of radio rivalry, and have for over a decade asserted that
satellite radio offers a dangerous competitive threat. In advocating that regulators deny the
proposed merger, broadcasters document that its likely effect will be to provide satellite radio
listeners more, not less, service for their subscription dollar.
This market test for the XM-Sirius merger is clear to many. Economist David Henderson asks
if broadcasters would oppose the merger if they thought the merger would raise prices for what you
bought? His answer: Not likely.134 Gigi Sohn, president of Public Knowledge, also
sees the position of interested parties as key. It is no accident that the National Association of
Broadcasters is vigorously opposing this merger despite their protestations to the contrary,
they view satellite radio as a major competitor.135
Given that satellite radio accounts for under seven percent of radio broadcasting revenues,
treating satellite and terrestrial radio as competitors makes the case for merger approval
straightforward. Donald Russell, a 24-year veteran of the U.S. Department of Justice Antitrust
Division now a private antitrust attorney, asks: If satellite radio doesnt compete against
traditional broadcasters, why is the NAB making an all-out effort to block the
merger?136
The question was posed to Mark Cooper, director of research at the Consumer Federation of
America, who argued in this Wall Street Journal forum that regulators should block the merger. His
response was telling: The NAB would like to eliminate every shred of competition, no matter how
minor and indirect it is. That does not constitute evidence that such competition is effective or
sufficient to prevent abuse.137
Actually, so far as the merger is concerned, it does. That radio station owners are keen to
oppose the slightest shred of competition provides clarity to their broadcast signal. Any change
to reduce rivalry by merger to monopoly would be welcomed. Yet it is their reliably
self-interested opinion that the merger will not create monopoly, but more intense competition.
Precisely why this combination is in the consumers interest.
|
|
|
133 |
|
This is the implication of Prof. J. Gregory Sidaks analysis, as
discussed in Section V. |
|
134 |
|
David R. Henderson, Sirius Business, Wall
Street Journal (Feb. 28, 2007), p. A15. |
|
135 |
|
Gigi Sohn, The XM-Sirius Merger and the Public Interest, Public
Knowledge (April 6, 2007);
http://www.publicknowledge.org/node/903. |
|
136 |
|
Reply All: Is XM-Sirius Good for Consumers?, Wall
Street Journal (Feb. 27, 2007) |
|
137 |
|
Ibid. |
45
|
|
|
|
|
Thomas W. Hazlett
|
|
The Economics of the Satellite Radio Merger
|
|
|
APPENDIX 1
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Appendix 1. NAB Statements On Terrestrial Vs. Satellite Radio Competition |
Name of FCC Proceeding |
|
Date |
|
NAB Position |
|
page |
|
|
Filed |
|
|
|
|
|
Response of NAB to
American Mobile Radio
Corporations
Reply and Opposition to
Petitions to Deny in
File Nos.
26/27-DSS-LA-93;
IO/l I-DSS-P-93
|
|
25-Jun-93
|
|
[U]nderlying NABs concern over the
proposed expansion of an already
saturated marketplace is the loss of
local service communities will face as
currently struggling stations are pushed
over the financial precipice.
|
|
3 |
Response of NAB to
American Mobile Radio
Corporations
Reply and Opposition to
Petitions to Deny in
File Nos.
26/27-DSS-LA-93;
IO/l I-DSS-P-93
|
|
25-Jun-93
|
|
[S]atellite DARS systems will
immeasurably injure terrestrial radio
stations by siphoning off listeners with
their thirty or more channels of new programming.
|
|
3 |
Response of NAB to
American Mobile Radio
Corporations
Reply and Opposition to
Petitions to Deny in
File Nos.
26/27-DSS-LA-93;
IO/l I-DSS-P-93
|
|
25-Jun-93
|
|
AMRC asserts that because it intends to rely
on subscriptions and not advertising sales for
profits, it would not be competing with
terrestrial broadcasters in a manner sufficient to
drive marginal stations off the air, and it
summarily dismisses competitive concerns. This
conclusion is untenable. A radio stations
product, what it sells. is numbers of
listeners, its ratings. Satellite DARS of
necessity will cut into terrestrial broadcasting
audiences. As a result, stations which are already
struggling to remain financially viable will be
incredibly hard pressed to persevere, with lower
ratings, and thus lower ad dollars paid for
lower numbers.
|
|
3-4 |
Response of NAB to
American Mobile Radio
Corporations
Reply and Opposition to
Petitions to Deny in
File Nos.
26/27-DSS-LA-93;
IO/l I-DSS-P-93
|
|
25-Jun-93
|
|
[L]ocal programming is
relatively expensive to produce. As the audience
for such programming is
fractured between the local station(s) and satellite
DARS programming. the
ability of a terrestrial station to support its
local product will evaporate.
|
|
5 |
46
|
|
|
|
|
Thomas W. Hazlett
|
|
The Economics of the Satellite Radio Merger
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Comments of the NAB, Gen. Docket
No. 90-357
|
|
13-Nov-90
|
|
Any success of satellite-based audio broadcast services would likely be
at the expense of local broadcast stations, in that satellite services would
affect the amount of advertising placed on local radio stations, and the
related cost of air time on the stations rate card. Due to the inherent non-local nature of satellite-distributed services, if commercial satellite audio
broadcasting services were to be based on advertising, rather than on
subscription fees, a substantial percentage of the revenues would likely come
from existing national and/or regional advertisers. Consequently, the existing
foundation of advertising revenues, supporting current local radio services,
would be affected, perhaps significantly.
|
|
14 |
Comments of the NAB, Gen. Docket
No. 90-357
|
|
13-Nov-90
|
|
Should radios national/regional
advertising revenues migrate to new satellite-delivered audio services,
conceivably this could translate into a potential loss of almost a fifth of the
total economic base of the entire radio broadcasting industry in the United
States. While total loss of all national/regional revenues is possible, a more
likely scenario is a loss of an increasing percentage of national/regional ad
dollars.
|
|
14 |
Comments of the NAB, Gen. Docket
No. 90-357
|
|
13-Nov-90
|
|
The viability of local radio stations in the United States could be
seriously threatened by major advertising market realignments caused by
communications policies promoting two rival radio distribution markets one
local, and one national/regional. The effect of heavy losses in
national/regional revenues would not likely be evenly distributed among local
broadcasting stations. The impact would most likely fall hardest on the class
of stations most vulnerable at this time AM stations.
|
|
15 |
Comments of the NAB, Gen. Docket
No. 90-357
|
|
13-Nov-90
|
|
[W]ith the advent of a
satellite-audio service configured on a nationwide distribution model,
financial support is more likely to be siphoned from radios national
advertising base rather than from new, unknown and unidentified sources.
|
|
17 |
Comments of the NAB, Gen. Docket
No. 90-357
|
|
13-Nov-90
|
|
[T]he introduction of a new, national radio broadcast competitor could be
expected to have a more direct effect on audiences and advertisers than any of
todays non-broadcast media services. The system and concept of broadcasting
is well-known and understood by American audiences. Due to this familiarity
factor alone, satellite-delivered digital audio services may have an edge in
competing with non-broadcast distribution media. And more to the point,
services that generally sound, operate, and are received over-the-air,
just like radio, on automobile, home stereo, and portable receivers, might
attract specific segments of the listening audience (i.e., especially those
in mobile vehicles) and thus affect local broadcasting stations much more than
do CDs, DAT or new cable audio services.
|
|
18 |
NAB petition
to deny in re: Satellite
Radio, Inc.
8-DSS-DISC-91(Z);
49/50-DSS-P/U-90;
I58/59-DSS-&VEND-90
|
|
18-Mar-91
|
|
Satellite CDs proposed private
satellite sound broadcasting system will compete directly with NAB member
stations for listening audience. Because the stations revenues depend on the
size of their listening audience, the loss of listening audience to Satellite
CD will adversely affect the stations economically.
|
|
1-2 |
47
|
|
|
|
|
Thomas W. Hazlett
|
|
The Economics of the Satellite Radio Merger
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Reply comments of the NAB,
Gen.
Docket No. 90-357
|
|
20-Oct-95
|
|
DARS will bring only minimal new benefits to the vast majority of
the listening public, but will, with its certain duplication of mainstream
formats and its sure diversion of audiences and fragmentation of advertising,
lessen the ability of traditional radio stations everywhere to provide quality
local programming and community services.
|
|
2 |
Reply comments of the NAB,
Gen. Docket No. 90-357
|
|
20-Oct-95
|
|
[T]he efficiencies to
be offered to advertisers suggest that nationwide DARS would have competitive
advantages to compete with incumbent broadcasters.
|
|
4 |
Reply comments of the NAB,
Gen. Docket No. 90-357
|
|
20-Oct-95
|
|
Three of the
DARS Proponents, in their comments, blatantly misrepresent the reach of
terrestrial radio by referencing only the reach of FM radio signals by
referencing only FM stations as just described, it becomes clear that the DARS
applicants are really focused not on the smaller stations, but on the audience
of the larger stations (FM), the larger populations, the real numbers and the
real dollars.
|
|
6-7 |
Reply comments of the NAB,
Gen. Docket No. 90-359
|
|
20-Oct-95
|
|
[T]he fact that radio listenership in cars
continues to grow does not mean that the inclusion of CD and cassette players
in cars has not diverted radio listenership in cars. We submit that the fact
that radio listenership in autos has continued to grow is much more a function
of the fact that over the last several years people have been experiencing
longer commutes in their cars and therefore all listening in cars has
dramatically increases. Moreover CDs and cassettes are simply not fungible
products with radio, in that CDs and cassettes must be purchased,
transported to the car and selected and, they do not have the personality
or commentary of announcers.
|
|
24 |
Reply comments of the NAB,
Gen. Docket No. 90-359
|
|
20-Oct-95
|
|
[S]atellite DARS will have a
competitive impact on terrestrial stations in every radio market no matter what
its regulatory classification
|
|
34 |
Reply Comments of the NAB,
Gen. Docket No. 90-359;
The Truth About Satellite
Radio, Attachment
|
|
20-Oct-95
|
|
The primary audiences of local
radio and satellite radio are the same: home/office/auto. They will compete
directly for local market share.
|
|
2 |
NAB Petition for
Declaratory
Ruling, IB Docket No. 95-91
GEN Docket No. 90-357
|
|
14-Apr-04
|
|
In lieu of the promised niche
audiences, foreign language services, senior and childrens programming, [XM
and Sirius] have instead devoted substantial bandwidth to compete directly with
local broadcasters with local content, without being subject to any public
interest obligations.
|
|
i |
NAB Petition for
Declaratory Ruling, IB
Docket No. 95-91 GEN
Docket No. 90-357
|
|
14-Apr-04
|
|
NAB conducted extensive studies which
showed the economic harm a national satellite radio service would have on local
broadcasters and their ability to serve their local communities ... The SPR
Study, along with a study provided by Kagan Media Appraisals, are replete with
evidence of the relative fragility of local radio service and how it could be
severely impacted by diversion of the audience to SDARS.
|
|
8 |
48
|
|
|
|
|
Thomas W. Hazlett
|
|
The Economics of the Satellite Radio Merger
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
NAB Petition for
Declaratory
Ruling, IB
Docket No.
95-91 GEN
Docket No.
90-357
|
|
14-Apr-04
|
|
[T]he majority of XM and Sirius lineups are music
channels that are essentially are [sic] duplicative of formats offered by
terrestrial radio, albeit broken down by channels into subcategories by
music genre ... Instead of fulfilling their commitments to serve children,
senior citizens, ethnic and foreign language communities, XM and Sirius have
devoted their bandwidth to variations on traditional, mainstream programming.
|
|
11-12; 13 |
NAB Petition
for
Declaratory
Ruling, IB
Docket No.
95-91 GEN
Docket No.
90-357
|
|
14-Apr-04
|
|
In lieu of the promised niche audiences ... they have instead
devoted substantial bandwidth to compete directly with local broadcasters with
local content, without being subject to any public interest obligations ... A
centralized localized service, which is essentially duplicative of existing
programming, does little to foster diversity and localism: it can only exist to
the detriment of the dissemination of free and over-the-air local services
to local communities.
|
|
17 |
NAB Reply
Comments to
NAB Petition
for
Declaratory
Ruling, MB
Docket
No.
04-160
|
|
21-June-04
|
|
What was true in 1995 is still true today
if SDARS is allowed to penetrate the local
market, local
broadcasting, and the voice of the community it provides, will suffer ... With
the addition of local traffic and weather, satellite radio is no longer an
exclusively national service; and its impact on terrestrial broadcasting is
growing and could quickly evolve into a force in the local advertising market.
How much harm, however, is largely dependent on Commissions decision in this
proceeding and timely FCC action.
|
|
15-16 |
Note: Footnotes omitted
49